Skip to main content

Main menu

  • Home
  • Articles
    • Current
    • Special Feature Articles - Most Recent
    • Special Features
    • Colloquia
    • Collected Articles
    • PNAS Classics
    • List of Issues
  • Front Matter
    • Front Matter Portal
    • Journal Club
  • News
    • For the Press
    • This Week In PNAS
    • PNAS in the News
  • Podcasts
  • Authors
    • Information for Authors
    • Editorial and Journal Policies
    • Submission Procedures
    • Fees and Licenses
  • Submit
  • Submit
  • About
    • Editorial Board
    • PNAS Staff
    • FAQ
    • Accessibility Statement
    • Rights and Permissions
    • Site Map
  • Contact
  • Journal Club
  • Subscribe
    • Subscription Rates
    • Subscriptions FAQ
    • Open Access
    • Recommend PNAS to Your Librarian

User menu

  • Log in
  • My Cart

Search

  • Advanced search
Home
Home
  • Log in
  • My Cart

Advanced Search

  • Home
  • Articles
    • Current
    • Special Feature Articles - Most Recent
    • Special Features
    • Colloquia
    • Collected Articles
    • PNAS Classics
    • List of Issues
  • Front Matter
    • Front Matter Portal
    • Journal Club
  • News
    • For the Press
    • This Week In PNAS
    • PNAS in the News
  • Podcasts
  • Authors
    • Information for Authors
    • Editorial and Journal Policies
    • Submission Procedures
    • Fees and Licenses
  • Submit
Research Article

Understanding the social context of the Schelling segregation model

William A. V. Clark and Mark Fossett
  1. aUniversity of California, Los Angeles, CA 90095; and
  2. cTexas A&M University, College Station, TX 77843

See allHide authors and affiliations

PNAS March 18, 2008 105 (11) 4109-4114; https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0708155105
William A. V. Clark
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  • For correspondence: wclark@geog.ucla.edu
Mark Fossett
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  1. Edited by Susan Hanson, Clark University, Worcester, MA, and approved January 22, 2008 (received for review August 30, 2007)

  • Article
  • Figures & SI
  • Info & Metrics
  • PDF
Loading

Abstract

A recent article [Vinkovic D, Kirman A (2006) Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 103:19261–19265] showing that the Schelling model has a physical analogue extends our understanding of the model. However, prior research has already outlined a mathematical basis for the Schelling model and simulations based on it have already enhanced our understanding of the social dynamics that underlie the model, something that the physical analogue does not address. Research in social science has provided a formal basis for the segregative outcomes resulting from the residential selection process and simulations have replicated relevant spatial outcomes under different specifications of the residential dynamics. New and increasingly detailed survey data on preferences demonstrates the embeddedness of the Schelling selection process in the social behaviors of choosing alternative residential compositions. It also demonstrates that, in the multicultural context, seemingly mild preferences for living with similar neighbors carry the potential to be strong determinants for own race selectivity and residential segregation.

  • preferences
  • simulation
  • ethnicity
  • integration
  • neighborhoods

A recent article outlined a model that can explain the way in which separation or segregation (clustering) can arise in physical processes and is thus a parallel to the clustering outcomes of the Schelling segregation model (1). The physical analogue is interesting and it is intriguing to learn that there are physical parallels to social processes with specific commonalities in the physical processes of clustering and the social process of residential separation and segregation. That said, it is not completely clear that we have advanced our understanding of segregation and segregation dynamics by generating a physical analogue to the Schelling model. Although the physical analogue explains clustering and separating, the most important issue in the Schelling model, from a social perspective, is how choices play out in the social fabric and lead to segregated residential patterns. We show here that there are well articulated mathematical explanations for social segregation, that simulation studies with relatively simple utility structures can replicate complex and sometimes subtle segregation patterns seen in real urban environments, and that data from surveys of preferences reiterate the role of social distance in segregation outcomes.

The original Schelling agent model was disarmingly simple in its construction (2, 3). It posited that an agent, a model representation of a household that could be white or black, preferred to be on a square on a checkerboard in which half or more of the eight adjacent neighbors were of a similar color. In the economic context, this was seen as having utility one compared with having utility zero. Schelling used simple simulations based on such hypothetical preference schedules to show that the adjustments of individual households responding to changes in composition on the checkerboard invariably lead to complete segregation (3). New survey evidence for different groups makes it possible to base preference schedules for simulation studies on empirical findings instead of using hypothetical schedules as Schelling did (4). As we review below, preference schedules based on surveys indicate that households do typically favor residing with households of similar color.

The Schelling model was of mostly theoretical interest and was rarely cited (5) until a significant debate about the extent and explanations of residential segregation in U.S. urban areas was engaged in the 1980s and 1990s (6, 7). To that point, most social scientists offered an explanation for segregation that invoked housing discrimination, principally by whites, as the major force in explaining why there was residential separation in the urban fabric (8). Reevaluation of the explanations for residential separation suggested that individual preferences alone, and in combination with economic differences among ethnic groups, could play an important role in explaining patterns of residential separation (9). The Schelling model was critical in providing a theoretical basis for viewing residential preferences as relevant to understanding the ethnic patterns observed in metropolitan areas. Furthermore, its implications have been buttressed by accumulated findings on preferences in multicultural settings which show that all major racial and ethnic groups hold preferences that are as strong as or stronger than the relatively mild preferences Schelling considered in his original two-group formulation.

The underlying basis of residential preferences is a matter of ongoing debate and a full review of the issues is beyond the scope of this study. In brief, preferences have complex origins and emerge from the social psychology, group dynamics, and history of racial and ethnic relations. Many plausible views have been offered. For example, it has been suggested that preferences reflect attachments to group identity and group culture (e.g., language, religion, beliefs, norms, customs, music, art, etc.) formed in early socialization, the salience of ethnicity in personal identity and sense of social position, and ethnocentric evaluations wherein individuals favor their own group's culture over other group cultures. It also has been suggested that preferences are shaped by expectations and stereotypes, founded or unfounded, that coethnics will provide reciprocal acceptance and support; that other groups may be indifferent, unwelcoming, or overtly hostile; that residing in ethnic neighborhoods may be convenient and carry practical benefits; and that neighborhood ethnic mix is predictive of future neighborhood conditions and home values.

None of these possibilities is implausible and none are mutually exclusive of others, so all can be entertained simultaneously. Significantly, however, the basis of residential preferences is not crucial to assessing their implications for segregation. This is clear in mathematical formulations and computer simulation models. In such contexts, particular preferences for coethnic contact produce identical residential choices and patterns of residential segregation regardless of the presumed basis of the preference. Thus, from any point of view, groups' patterns of evaluating the presence of households similar to and different from themselves may be relevant to understanding the outcomes of residential selection.

The more important distinction in the literature is the distinction between preferences and discrimination. Two key points are especially relevant. First, scholarly research and fair housing legislation maintain logical and legal distinctions between voluntary residential choices guided by preferences and involuntary constraints on housing choices resulting from housing discrimination, intimidation, and violence. Second, policy options for promoting integration differ dramatically for these two factors. Discrimination is prohibited by law and is subject to a variety of legal remedies. Preferences are outside the purview of fair housing law and remedies, if sought, will necessarily be fundamentally different. In view of this, it is crucial to gain a better understanding of the impact preferences may have on segregation.

Mathematical Derivations and Agent-Based Models

Schelling's analyses of the implications of preference schedules suggested that mixed-race residential neighborhoods are not likely to be stable. Young (10) provides rigorous theoretical analyses supporting and extending Schelling's insights. Similarly, Zhang (11, 12) also has shown mathematically that segregation will result under the Schelling model, even when everyone desires integration. Specifically, he shows that segregation is a stochastically stable state “that tends to emerge and persist in the long run regardless of the initial state” (12, p 548). The finding that separation will occur even when most people prefer integrated neighborhoods is important because it may help us explain the persistence of separation even in a world that is increasingly tolerant and where society has made significant strides toward reducing discrimination in the housing market. “Without any discriminatory behavior in the housing market a slight preference for like-color neighbors … can give rise to a high level of residential segregation and cause it to persist” (11, p 164).

Formal analysis indicates that even asymmetric preferences for same-group contact can be sufficient to create segregated patterns under the Schelling model. Zhang established this for the two-color case with a preference for own color by one group and neutral preferences by the other group by drawing on the theory of stochastic dynamical systems and the method of agent modeling. Building on work in evolutionary game theory, he showed that even slight asymmetry in residential preferences between two groups will produce endogenous segregation. The basic model considers a set of n neighbors, either four in the rook's case, or eight in the queen's case, on a checkerboard lattice. Each of the locations may have a black agent or a white agent, or may be vacant. Price of housing is introduced, but not housing quality (all units are assumed to be of the same quality) and a market mechanism determines the price of housing. In the “housing market” (the locations of the lattice checkerboard), a “natural vacancy rate” facilitates housing market turnover. There is no restriction on the agent choices, but white agents prefer to live near whites whereas black agents are neutral with respect to their choices. In each period, a pair of locations is chosen randomly and a set of possible outcomes includes a black agent moving to a vacant location, a white agent moving to a vacant location, a black agent exchanging locations with a white agent, a black agent with a black agent, and a white agent with a white agent. The agents make choices based on their individual utilities but decisions are boundedly rational and agents may make utility-decreasing moves.

Under the conditions outlined earlier, Zhang shows that S, the set of all states that maximizes the sum of all agents' utilities, is stochastically stable. Significantly, if blacks are color neutral, and whites have a slight preference for like-colored neighbors (say a least a 60–70% preference), the results are intriguing: residential segregation emerges, vacancy rates are higher in areas with black concentrations, and whites pay more for housing. The results Zhang obtains by using a game-theoretic framework are powerful; they move the Schelling model from a set of general statements and an inductive approach to neighborhood selection to a “precisely defined mathematical concept” (11, p 164) where neighborhood transitions are determined by a set of utility functions. Young (10) similarly provides rigorous formal foundations for Schelling's most basic insights.

Preferences, Tolerance, and the Basis of Simulation Models

There has been a long history of simulating the Schelling model. Early models were spare and simple, but advances in computing capabilities make it more feasible than ever to use simulation approaches to explore how residential outcomes vary over a wide range of increasingly complex and realistic model inputs (13, 14). For example, a recent model incorporates the role of multiple types of preferences, multiple ethnic groups, urban and demographic conditions, and intergroup inequality in socioeconomic status (15). Models of this sort expand our ability to investigate the residential patterns that emerge when agent choices are guided by different preference distributions, including both hypothetical distributions and ones fashioned after results from survey studies.

A core feature of agent models is the use of game-theoretic contexts with feedback loops. In the standard two-group simulation, agents may be open to living in mixed neighborhoods and seek only to avoid being in the minority (i.e., less than half the population). However, their moves to satisfy this objective—that is, moving from an area where their group is in the minority to one where it is at least half—change the ethnic mix in both locations in a way that precipitates further movement. The neighborhood they leave becomes less attractive to members of their group and the neighborhood they enter becomes less attractive to members of the other group. Over successive iterations, homogeneous neighborhoods emerge.

The limitations of nonexperimental research make it difficult to evaluate the effects of different factors on segregation in real cities. Consequently, there has been a contentious debate between those who focus on the role of social distance and preferences as potential explanatory forces in creating separation, and those who invoke the effects of housing discrimination. Because neither group can establish empirically grounded evaluations of the effects of either preferences or discrimination, recent work has focused on the logical standing of explanations based on social distance asking, “Is it reasonable to entertain the hypothesis that social distance and preference dynamics could generate and sustain significant levels of segregation in the absence of discrimination” (15). The mathematical formulations we reviewed earlier suggest that segregation can arise from simple preferences for own-race neighbors. Below we show that simulations based on observed ethnic preferences also provide quantitative and qualitative (visual) evidence for this possible residential dynamic.

An extensive literature exists on preferences and their implications for residential separation. An early study of Detroit used survey flash cards depicting different racial residential neighborhood combinations to establish that blacks generally preferred neighborhoods that were half black and half white, but whites generally preferred neighborhoods that were nearly all white (16). Subsequent studies of other metropolitan areas replicated this finding (17, 18) and also documented similar patterns in the preferences of other racial and ethnic groups (9). Focusing on white–black differences, the finding that most white households want majority white neighborhoods, whereas most African American households prefer neighborhoods that are at least half black—with a 50/50 black–white composition most preferred— is central to arguments that preferences may contribute to group residential separation in cities. Two lines of reasoning support this conclusion. The first and most obvious is that the modal preferences for whites and blacks are not compatible—most African American households want a neighborhood that is at least 50% black, but few whites prefer such neighborhoods. Neighborhoods with a 50/50 ethnic mix are thus inherently unstable. Blacks are willing to enter and stay, but whites will not enter or stay. This provides insight into the role of preferences in the dynamics of residential “tipping”; the often observed outcome where neighborhoods that become 20–30% minority often continue on to become majority minority (19). Recent studies have contributed to our understanding of how other race avoidance impacts the likelihood of particular neighborhood selection (20) and patterns of neighborhood change (21).

There is a less obvious basis for linking preferences to segregation that has been termed “the paradox of weak minority preferences” (15). Setting whites' preferences aside completely, minority preferences for 50/50 neighborhoods are rarely compatible with integration. Citywide integration obtains when all neighborhoods match the ethnic mix of the city. But few metropolitan areas have ethnic mixes that correspond to minority preferences for neighborhood ethnic mix. So the thought experiment of arranging neighborhoods to match blacks' residential preferences for 50/50 racial mix does not lead to low segregation scores. To the contrary, for most metropolitan areas, the exercise produces substantial segregation (15).

The Metropolitan Study of Urban Inequality provides rich data on group preferences for neighborhood composition. Here, we review data on “ideal” neighborhood ethnic composition. Respondents were asked to populate an “ideal” neighborhood—a 3 × 5 grid of housing units centered on the respondent's home—with households from four ethnic groups (whites, blacks, Hispanics, and Asians). The answers register preferences for same-group neighbors and also preferences regarding neighbors from other groups. The data we review are for the four race/ethnic groups in Los Angeles, a harbinger of America's increasingly multicultural metropolitan areas.

Fig. 1 summarizes the ethnic distributions that respondents from the four groups gave for the eight housing units surrounding to the respondent's home. These results for adjacent neighbors indicate that all groups prefer a majority or near-majority of their surrounding neighbors in an ideal neighborhood to be of the same race/ethnicity although with varying mixes of other groups. Significantly, the ethnic distributions for the eight adjacent locations are fundamentally similar. This indicates that it is appropriate to compare groups in terms of their overall preference pattern. Doing so leads straightaway to an obvious but powerful conclusion: none of groups has a preference distribution that is compatible with that of any other group.

Fig. 1.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 1.

Race and ethnic choices for ideal neighborhood cell composition.

The diagram provides insight into how preferences may promote separation in the residential mosaic. Regarding preferences for same-race neighbors, the ideal neighborhood results are consistent with previous findings that all groups prefer areas where their group is a majority or near-majority. The range of variation is modest; a bit <50% in the case of African Americans and >50% in the case of Asians. Regarding preferences for other groups, there are notable differences between responses for blacks and whites compared with responses for Hispanics and Asians. In general, blacks and whites express relative neutrality regarding the composition of other-group neighbors. In contrast, Asians indicate a clear preference for whites over blacks and Hispanics and, similarly, Hispanics prefer whites over blacks and Asians. These details reinforce the basic conclusion that no two groups seek neighborhoods with similar ethnic composition.

Fig. 2 presents the data on ideal ethnic mix of neighbors from another perspective. It gives each group's distribution of responses regarding the preferred number of same-group households for the eight adjacent housing units surrounding the respondent's home. The possible counts range from 0 to 8. The diagrams depict possible spatial structures for each count varying from own-group dominance to own-group minority status. These are illustrative; individual responses did not necessarily correspond to the exact spatial structures depicted. The figure shows that most respondents chose middle-range outcomes on same-group presence. There are few choices for either isolation or complete dominance. The most common response sets for ideal neighborhoods are in the range of majority or near-majority same-group presence. Blacks show the greatest openness to minority status within a neighborhood. Even so, 60% of blacks express a preference for near half (i.e., 3 of 8) or greater same-group presence. The figures for Hispanics, whites, and Asians are higher at 66%, 72%, and 75%, respectively. Because no group expresses a preference for minority status, no conceivable neighborhood ethnic mix can satisfy the preferences of all groups.

Fig. 2.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 2.

Own-race preferences in an ideal neighborhood composition.

Simulations

Segregation simulations implement simplified behavioral rules within a specified urban structure and examine the resulting residential outcomes to gain insights into how social dynamics may shape the realities that we observe in cities (15, 22). According to the conventions of agent modeling, agents are “virtual households with the ability to search in virtual housing markets” and make residential choices. Households have preferences for coethnic contact specified as the percentage presence of coethnic households in the neighborhood the household lives in or is considering moving to. The SimSeg model we use runs in a fashion similar to all agent models, but with greater capabilities than most previous simulations of residential dynamics. The model's key features and algorithms are described in detail elsewhere (15). In brief, it creates housing units of varying quality and places them at residential locations across the city. It then populates this virtual city with households of different ethnic and socioeconomic status (income) and distributes them randomly to housing units. Ethnic segregation in the city thus initially reflects only random departure from even distribution. During the simulations households move according to the rules of the model by making residential choices guided by three separate and independent preference concerns: goals for housing quality, goals for neighborhood income, and goals for neighborhood ethnic composition. The program calculates segregation scores over the course of the simulation so trends in segregation can be assessed quantitatively and qualitatively based on graphical representations of the city's residential distributions.

We present results from simulation experiments crafted to explore the implications of ethnic preferences in multigroup situations similar to those discussed previously. For simplicity, we consider a situation with three groups—blue, red, and green—and even demographic proportions (34%, 33%, and 33%, respectively). d , e Households are assigned ethnic prefer-ences; that is, targets for same-group presence in neighborhoods. f We vary these in magnitude in different simulations to bracket the range of preferences reported in surveys. In addition, all households in all groups are assigned preferences for high-quality housing (relative to what they can afford) and preferences to reside in areas with high-average income. Households give identical weight to all three preferences, so goals regarding area ethnic composition are just one among several important goals shaping the location decisions households make.

Households “see” neighborhoods based on diamond-shaped local areas consisting of the 40 housing units within four cardinal moves of a focal housing unit. g Households evaluate neighborhood ethnic composition and average income based on the population residing in the local area. As in real urban areas, the city is given a significant city–suburb gradient on housing quality with low-income housing being concentrated in the center. In addition, the city has a high-income group (blues) and two low-income groups (reds and greens) whose average income is 30% below the average for the high-income group. The city–suburb housing gradient creates pronounced segregation along socioeconomic lines, but its impact on ethnic segregation is modest. At initialization, the two low-income ethnic groups are more centralized, but their overall segregation from the high-income ethnic group is not great (15).

We present representative examples of simulation results in Fig. 3. h Each row corresponds to a single simulation experiment and contains a sequence of images depicting the city's residential distribution at four points in the experiment. Ethnic segregation is seen visually when households of different colors (i.e., blue, red, and green) cluster together on the city landscape. In addition, a quantitative segregation index—the variance ratio (V)—is computed for each of the three possible two-group comparisons. i The scores are plotted in the graph on the right-hand side of the figure. Socioeconomic segregation is seen visually based on high-income households being depicted in darker shades and low-income households in lighter shades. Accordingly, the central areas are lighter and the outlying areas are darker. Socioeconomic segregation is not our main focus, so we have omitted quantitative results to save space.

Fig. 3.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 3.

Animation sequences and segregation trends by targets for coethnic contact.

The key feature of the simulations is that we vary in-group preference targets assigned to households from levels substantially below those documented in surveys (e.g., 20%) to levels similar to those documented in surveys (e.g., 40–60%) and beyond. j Several important patterns are evident in the results. One is that ethnic segregation is low at the beginning of every simulation; not surprising because it primarily reflects random departure from even distribution. Another is that ethnic segregation emerges quickly and stabilizes at high levels when preferences for same-group contact are similar to those documented in surveys. The crucial transition occurs when preference targets reach or exceed a group's population representation (22). Thus, high levels of segregation emerge when targets for same-group contact shift from 20% to 40%. Segregation is low when households seek 20% same-group contact because all households can be satisfied in neighborhoods that match the city's ethnic mix. This is not the case when all households seek 40% same-group contact; accordingly, high levels of segregation emerge. Perhaps surprising to some, raising targets for same-group contact to even higher levels has minimal additional impact on the overall level of segregation or the speed with which it emerges. This is anticipated by previous studies (2, 10, 11, 12, 22) that note that, once certain critical thresholds are crossed, preferences tend to drive local areas toward homogeneity.

Space does not permit a full discussion of how Schelling-style segregation effects vary with agent vision. But we offer a few comments to place the results just reviewed in perspective. Agent vision (i.e., the local area the agent “sees”) can be specified as narrow (e.g., rook's and queen's neighborhoods), expansive (e.g., subdivisions, school districts, etc.), or intermediate in size (e.g., census blocks and block groups). Similarly, vision can be specified in terms of either bounded areas or local areas. Prior research shows that the form of segregation will vary with vision. When agent vision is narrow, segregation will emerge first at small spatial scales and build to larger scales only over long periods of time. When agent vision is intermediate or expansive, segregation will emerge straightaway at larger spatial scales. When agent vision follows bounded areas, segregation will follow area boundaries and can produce “checkering” if agents evaluate individual areas in isolation. If agent vision is local, ethnically homogeneous regions will have irregular shapes.

In the simulations we report here, we specified agent vision at an intermediate spatial scale (i.e., 40 housing units) approximately comparable in size to census blocks. As the graphical images show, this vision specification produces visually obvious clustering. Our specification of agent vision is consistent with research on residential choice, which indicates that households consider more than just adjacent housing units when making residential decisions. The vision specification we use is smaller than some relevant alternatives (e.g., large areas similar to school districts), but readily produces clustering patterns characteristic of urban areas without imposing undue computational burdens. k It is plausible that households might respond to multiple neighborhood definitions simultaneously (e.g., adjacent neighbors, city blocks, school districts, etc.). SimSeg can implement such possibilities, and studies exercising this capability indicate that the findings reported here hold so long as one of the area specifications involves intermediate or higher vision (24).

Bearing the simplifications of simulation analysis in mind, the graphical images of city residential distributions shown here are surprisingly consistent with contemporary urban residential patterns. In cases where ethnic preferences approximate survey results, city landscapes depict high levels of segregation by both socioeconomic status and ethnicity. Higher-income households from all groups are on the periphery of the urban structure and are spatially distant from lower-income households in the center. Likewise, whether in the lower-income center or the higher-income periphery, ethnic groups live apart from each other. This is comparable to patterns of residential formation that we see in our cities today. Thus, the simulations reveal that reasonable representations of the ongoing location decisions of households can create complex patterns of residential segregation. The visual outcomes and quantitative results constitute powerful evidence that social distance and preference dynamics do have the logical capacity to combine with socioeconomic inequality between groups to create relatively high levels of ethnic and class segregation. It is intriguing to note that the simulation results produce some subtle patterns often seen in real cities. Specifically, whereas the spatial separation of high-income and low-income households is great, socioeconomic differences between ethnic groups shape ethnic segregation in only limited ways. Group differences in socioeconomic standing have little impact on the segregation dimension of uneven distribution (which V measures), but minority socioeconomic disadvantage does serve to concentrate minority populations in high-poverty areas in the central city (15). In terms of potential social implications, it is obvious that this would foster disproportionate minority exposure to crime and other social problems found in high-poverty areas.

Significantly, the simulations here move beyond the Schelling two-color model to explore patterns of segregation in multiple group settings. In the increasing complexity of our metropolitan areas it is clearly important to analyze the dynamics of more than two groups. The most powerful finding from this is that there is little evidence of extensive integration among any combination of ethnic groups resulting from residential choices guided by ethnic preferences. As in real cities, minorities are segregated not only from the majority group, but also from each other. This pattern is not predicted by theories of housing discrimination by whites.

The data in Fig. 2 indicated that a nontrivial fraction of individuals in all groups say they would prefer neighborhoods where their group is not in the clear minority. Why don't the residential choices of these individuals promote more integrated outcomes? Formal analysis of the implications of preference-guided choices and agent simulations highlight the reason why; spatial outcomes are not determined by just the choices of one group, or the choices of the most tolerant members within a particular group. The dynamic nature of the residential sorting process drives the residential pattern toward nonminority status for all households and groups. When a household enters a neighborhood, the neighborhood becomes more attractive to members of the household's own group and less attractive to members of other groups. Unless most households are strongly averse to majority status—and surveys indicate this is not the case, local neighborhoods will drift toward ethnic homogeneity. The resulting neighborhood structure is more segregated than most individual households would find “ideal.”

These results indicate that the potential relevance of ethnic preferences for segregation cannot easily be discounted. Some have suggested that prevailing ethnic preferences would permit substantial integration if other segregation-promoting dynamics (e.g., housing discrimination) were eliminated. This hypothesis is contradicted by formal theory and by simulation results such as we have presented here. Of course, although our attention here is narrowly focused on preference effects, we do not gainsay the fact that other important social dynamics also are present in urban life and exert independent effects on segregation (25). At the same time, we must stress that acknowledging the relevance of other factors does not undermine the conclusions we offer regarding preference effects. It is a mistake to suggest, as some have, that preference effects can be relevant only when other factors are irrelevant. To the contrary, none of the factors segregation theorists consider as relevant are mutually exclusive of each other. So it is highly plausible that segregation is produced by multiple factors operating in combination.

In the context where multiple factors may be impacting aggregate spatial patterns, it is difficult to definitively assess the impact of any single dynamic, especially by using nonexperimental data. l Simulation and agent modeling present a useful option for investigating segregation dynamics in this situation. They provide a means for exploring the possible outcomes of complex social processes and they can illuminate how complex macro outcomes may arise from simple microbehavioral dynamics. The social sciences have been slow to embrace these tools, but their potential value is becoming increasingly apparent. As the literature advances, agent models have great potential to help us to better understand the real-world dynamics of the city. Already, they have provided a basis for arguing that preferences, social distance dynamics, and residential choices cannot be dismissed as possible explanations of segregation outcomes. As the models continue to be refined, they may inform the debate about alternate explanations for segregation in the urban landscape even further.

Observations and Conclusions

Our article shows that there is now a rigorous mathematical basis for the Schelling model and increasingly refined methods for simulating the impact of preferences and social distance dynamics. The results establish clearly that to ignore the role of choice behavior based on own-race preferences is to ignore a potentially important influence of racial and ethnic dynamics in the residential fabric. Of course, much work remains to be done to assess how segregation dynamics may change in an increasingly multiethnic society. For example, as the number of mixed race/ethnic individuals continues to increase, segregation patterns will be further complicated by their residential selections. Preliminary evidence suggests that mixed-race households are more likely to live in integrated neighborhoods than in homogeneous concentrations of either of their parental races or ethnicities.

Intra- and intergroup inequality in socioeconomic status both continue at high levels, racial and ethnic status continue to have high salience in social relations, and survey evidence shows that people generally strive to live with others who are similar to them with respect to ethnic and socioeconomic status. All of this suggests that we will continue to see significant levels of residential separation in the residential fabric (26). Although it is a question of some debate, there is at present no basis for anticipating evenness to emerge in racial and ethnic spatial distributions in our cities. Practices of legal, institutional race exclusion have been substantially dismantled, but stereotypes and prejudice remain and can promote residential separation in the absence of housing discrimination. Equally importantly, people with similar social characteristics often congregate in the same neighborhoods based on mutual attraction, common interests, and shared sensibilities (27).

Past patterns of coercion and institutional practices such as race-restricted covenants produced involuntary separation by severely constraining housing options for minorities. But the emergence of affluent African American suburban communities in contemporary metropolitan areas is not easily explained in these terms. To the contrary, it is occurring in conjunction with expanding housing opportunities for middle class minorities and the rapid demise of exclusively white residential areas. It is suggestive of the power of positive ethnic association and the tendency for people to gravitate to the similar, the familiar, and the comfortable, especially when residing with other groups that may be indifferent or unwelcoming is not crucial for realizing other important residential outcomes (e.g., good schools, low crime, etc.). It further suggests that separation in the residential mosaic may diminish only slowly even as overt discrimination in housing declines and expressions of “racial tolerance” increase.

The implication of much commentary on urban areas is that the urban fabric would quickly become integrated if discrimination and other constraints on residential opportunities were eliminated (28). The preference and social distance work both in its mathematical and agent-based forms, and the survey results raise serious questions about this view (29). They suggest that mere tolerance and the absence of virulent housing discrimination will not produce integration under prevailing patterns of ethnic preference, at least, not in the short run. That the Schelling model has a physical analogue is interesting and theoretically illuminating is without question, but it is the social content of the Schelling model that gives it its power and importance. The implications of the mathematical formulations, simulation results, and survey evidence on preferences converge to suggest that we cannot presently expect rapid movement toward even spatial distributions of ethnic and racial groups and socioeconomic status groups. In view of this, further attention should be given to understanding how segregation in our metropolitan areas is shaped by the combination of substantial socioeconomic inequality within and between groups and social distance dynamics that reflect the salience of race-ethnicity and socioeconomic status in residential decisions.

Footnotes

  • bTo whom correspondence should be addressed. E-mail: wclark{at}geog.ucla.edu
  • Author contributions: W.A.V.C. and M.F. designed research, performed research, analyzed data, and wrote the paper.

  • The authors declare no conflict of interest.

  • This article is a PNAS Direct Submission.

  • ↵ d SimSeg can implement two- and three-group simulations. The shift from two to three groups is sufficient to reveal many differences in the implications of preferences in the multigroup context.

  • ↵ e This is a conservative setting because specifying groups as equal in size is optimal for maintaining integration in Schelling-style segregation models (22). Higher levels of segregation result when we use more realistic demographic distributions (e.g., 65, 25, and 10).

  • ↵ f Targets for same-group presence are the same for all groups. We ran simulations in which preference targets were dispersed around the mean (as seen in the distributions in Fig. 2) and simulations in which targets were homogeneous. The results were similar either way, indicating that, in the main, preference effects revolve around the central tendency of the preference distribution.

  • ↵ g This specification is used in recent studies (22, 23) and is similar to the 5 × 5 square neighborhoods Schelling used in some simulations (2). Significantly, preference effects are robust over varying specifications of neighborhood size, shape, and type (e.g., bounded areas versus site-centered areas).

  • ↵ h The results shown here are from representative simulation experiments. We performed 500 replications for each design to establish the statistical norm for quantitative results.

  • ↵ i V is a well known measure with many attractive technical properties. We also computed scores for the more widely used dissimilarity index (D). Reporting V is a conservative choice; scores for D are always higher and suggest even more dramatic segregation results.

  • ↵ j We omit results for simulations with preferences set to zero. Not surprisingly, segregation did not emerge in these simulations.

  • ↵ k The shift from small-to-large scale segregation patterns occurs at low levels of agent vision (e.g., 4–16 units). Computational burden increases geometrically as local agent vision increases. Intermediate vision produces large-scale segregation with low computational burden.

  • ↵ l When multiple factors affect segregation, quantitative assessments of their separate effects depend critically on how the analysis is performed. When each is “added” or “removed” from a model system in which no other segregation dynamics are active, the impact can be large. However, when they are “added” or “removed” from a model system in which multiple segregation dynamics are active, their impact is usually small.

  • © 2008 by The National Academy of Sciences of the USA

References

  1. ↵
    1. Vinkovic D ,
    2. Kirman A
    (2006) Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 103:19261–19265.
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  2. ↵
    1. Schelling TC
    (1971) J Math Sociol 1:143–186.
    OpenUrl
  3. ↵
    1. Schelling TC
    (1978) Micromotives and Macrobehavior (Norton, New York).
  4. ↵
    1. Clark WAV
    (1991) Demography 28:1–19.
    OpenUrlPubMed
  5. ↵
    1. Skvoretz J
    (2006) J Math Sociol 30:181–184.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  6. ↵
    1. Galster G
    (1988) Popul Res Policy Rev 7:93–112.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  7. ↵
    1. Clark WAV
    (1988) Popul Res Policy Rev 7:113–121.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  8. ↵
    1. Massey D ,
    2. Denton N
    (1993) American Apartheid (Harvard Univ Press, Cambridge, MA).
  9. ↵
    1. Clark WAV
    (1992) Demography 30:451–466.
    OpenUrl
  10. ↵
    1. Young HP
    (1998) Individual Strategy and Social Structure: An Evolutionary Theory of Institutions (Princeton Univ Press, Princeton).
  11. ↵
    1. Zhang J
    (2004) J Math Sociol 28:147–170.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  12. ↵
    1. Zhang J
    (2004) J Econ Behav Organ 54:533–550.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  13. ↵
    1. Epstein JM ,
    2. Axtell R
    (1996) Growing Artificial Societies: Social Science from the Bottom Up (MIT Press, Cambridge MA).
  14. ↵
    1. Gaylord RJ ,
    2. D'Andria LJ
    (1998) Simulating Society: A Mathematica Toolkit for Modeling Socioeconomic Behavior (Springer, Amsterdam).
  15. ↵
    1. Fossett M
    (2006a) J Math Sociol 30:185–274.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  16. ↵
    1. Farley R ,
    2. Schuman H ,
    3. Bianchi S ,
    4. Colasanto D ,
    5. Hatchett S
    (1978) Soc Sci Res 7:319–344.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  17. ↵
    1. Armor D ,
    2. Clark WAV
    1. Armor D
    (1995) in Forced Justice, Housing segregation and school desegregation, ed Armor D (Oxford Univ Press, Oxford), pp 117–153.
  18. ↵
    1. Farley R ,
    2. Fielding E ,
    3. Krysan M
    (1997) Housing Policy Debate 8:763–800.
    OpenUrl
  19. ↵
    1. Galster G
    (1982) J Am Real Estate Urban Econ Assoc 10:39–60.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  20. ↵
    1. Sermons M
    (2000) Geogr Anal 32:225–246.
    OpenUrl
  21. ↵
    1. Ellen IG
    (2000) Sharing America's Neighborhoods: The Prospects for Stable Racial Integration (Harvard Univ Press, Cambridge, MA).
  22. ↵
    1. Fossett M ,
    2. Warren W
    (2005) Urban Stud 42:1893–1917.
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  23. ↵
    1. Laurie AJ ,
    2. Jaggi NK
    (2003) Urban Stud 40:2687–2704.
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  24. ↵
    1. Fossett M ,
    2. Dietrich D
    (2008) Environ Plan B, in press.
  25. ↵
    1. Brown LA ,
    2. Chung SY
    (2008) Ann Assoc Am Geogr 98:180–212.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  26. ↵
    1. Clark WAV
    (2002) Urban Geogr 23:237–256.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  27. ↵
    1. St. John C
    (2006) J Math Sociol 30:327–332.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  28. ↵
    1. Zubrinsky C ,
    2. Bobo L
    (1996) Soc Sci Res 25:335–374.
    OpenUrlCrossRefPubMed
  29. ↵
    1. Fossett M
    (2006b) J Math Sociol 30:289–298.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
PreviousNext
Back to top
Article Alerts
Email Article

Thank you for your interest in spreading the word on PNAS.

NOTE: We only request your email address so that the person you are recommending the page to knows that you wanted them to see it, and that it is not junk mail. We do not capture any email address.

Enter multiple addresses on separate lines or separate them with commas.
Understanding the social context of the Schelling segregation model
(Your Name) has sent you a message from PNAS
(Your Name) thought you would like to see the PNAS web site.
CAPTCHA
This question is for testing whether or not you are a human visitor and to prevent automated spam submissions.
Citation Tools
Understanding the social context of the Schelling segregation model
William A. V. Clark, Mark Fossett
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences Mar 2008, 105 (11) 4109-4114; DOI: 10.1073/pnas.0708155105

Citation Manager Formats

  • BibTeX
  • Bookends
  • EasyBib
  • EndNote (tagged)
  • EndNote 8 (xml)
  • Medlars
  • Mendeley
  • Papers
  • RefWorks Tagged
  • Ref Manager
  • RIS
  • Zotero
Request Permissions
Share
Understanding the social context of the Schelling segregation model
William A. V. Clark, Mark Fossett
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences Mar 2008, 105 (11) 4109-4114; DOI: 10.1073/pnas.0708155105
del.icio.us logo Digg logo Reddit logo Twitter logo CiteULike logo Facebook logo Google logo Mendeley logo
  • Tweet Widget
  • Facebook Like
  • Mendeley logo Mendeley
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences: 105 (11)
Table of Contents

Submit

Sign up for Article Alerts

Jump to section

  • Article
    • Abstract
    • Mathematical Derivations and Agent-Based Models
    • Preferences, Tolerance, and the Basis of Simulation Models
    • Simulations
    • Observations and Conclusions
    • Footnotes
    • References
  • Figures & SI
  • Info & Metrics
  • PDF

You May Also be Interested in

Water from a faucet fills a glass.
News Feature: How “forever chemicals” might impair the immune system
Researchers are exploring whether these ubiquitous fluorinated molecules might worsen infections or hamper vaccine effectiveness.
Image credit: Shutterstock/Dmitry Naumov.
Reflection of clouds in the still waters of Mono Lake in California.
Inner Workings: Making headway with the mysteries of life’s origins
Recent experiments and simulations are starting to answer some fundamental questions about how life came to be.
Image credit: Shutterstock/Radoslaw Lecyk.
Cave in coastal Kenya with tree growing in the middle.
Journal Club: Small, sharp blades mark shift from Middle to Later Stone Age in coastal Kenya
Archaeologists have long tried to define the transition between the two time periods.
Image credit: Ceri Shipton.
Illustration of groups of people chatting
Exploring the length of human conversations
Adam Mastroianni and Daniel Gilbert explore why conversations almost never end when people want them to.
Listen
Past PodcastsSubscribe
Panda bear hanging in a tree
How horse manure helps giant pandas tolerate cold
A study finds that giant pandas roll in horse manure to increase their cold tolerance.
Image credit: Fuwen Wei.

Similar Articles

Site Logo
Powered by HighWire
  • Submit Manuscript
  • Twitter
  • Facebook
  • RSS Feeds
  • Email Alerts

Articles

  • Current Issue
  • Special Feature Articles – Most Recent
  • List of Issues

PNAS Portals

  • Anthropology
  • Chemistry
  • Classics
  • Front Matter
  • Physics
  • Sustainability Science
  • Teaching Resources

Information

  • Authors
  • Editorial Board
  • Reviewers
  • Subscribers
  • Librarians
  • Press
  • Cozzarelli Prize
  • Site Map
  • PNAS Updates
  • FAQs
  • Accessibility Statement
  • Rights & Permissions
  • About
  • Contact

Feedback    Privacy/Legal

Copyright © 2021 National Academy of Sciences. Online ISSN 1091-6490