Skip to main content
  • Submit
  • About
    • Editorial Board
    • PNAS Staff
    • FAQ
    • Rights and Permissions
    • Site Map
  • Contact
  • Journal Club
  • Subscribe
    • Subscription Rates
    • Subscriptions FAQ
    • Open Access
    • Recommend PNAS to Your Librarian
  • Log in
  • My Cart

Main menu

  • Home
  • Articles
    • Current
    • Latest Articles
    • Special Features
    • Colloquia
    • Collected Articles
    • PNAS Classics
    • Archive
  • Front Matter
  • News
    • For the Press
    • Highlights from Latest Articles
    • PNAS in the News
  • Podcasts
  • Authors
    • Information for Authors
    • Purpose and Scope
    • Editorial and Journal Policies
    • Submission Procedures
    • For Reviewers
    • Author FAQ
  • Submit
  • About
    • Editorial Board
    • PNAS Staff
    • FAQ
    • Rights and Permissions
    • Site Map
  • Contact
  • Journal Club
  • Subscribe
    • Subscription Rates
    • Subscriptions FAQ
    • Open Access
    • Recommend PNAS to Your Librarian

User menu

  • Log in
  • My Cart

Search

  • Advanced search
Home
Home

Advanced Search

  • Home
  • Articles
    • Current
    • Latest Articles
    • Special Features
    • Colloquia
    • Collected Articles
    • PNAS Classics
    • Archive
  • Front Matter
  • News
    • For the Press
    • Highlights from Latest Articles
    • PNAS in the News
  • Podcasts
  • Authors
    • Information for Authors
    • Purpose and Scope
    • Editorial and Journal Policies
    • Submission Procedures
    • For Reviewers
    • Author FAQ

New Research In

Physical Sciences

Featured Portals

  • Physics
  • Chemistry
  • Sustainability Science

Articles by Topic

  • Applied Mathematics
  • Applied Physical Sciences
  • Astronomy
  • Computer Sciences
  • Earth, Atmospheric, and Planetary Sciences
  • Engineering
  • Environmental Sciences
  • Mathematics
  • Statistics

Social Sciences

Featured Portals

  • Anthropology
  • Sustainability Science

Articles by Topic

  • Economic Sciences
  • Environmental Sciences
  • Political Sciences
  • Psychological and Cognitive Sciences
  • Social Sciences

Biological Sciences

Featured Portals

  • Sustainability Science

Articles by Topic

  • Agricultural Sciences
  • Anthropology
  • Applied Biological Sciences
  • Biochemistry
  • Biophysics and Computational Biology
  • Cell Biology
  • Developmental Biology
  • Ecology
  • Environmental Sciences
  • Evolution
  • Genetics
  • Immunology and Inflammation
  • Medical Sciences
  • Microbiology
  • Neuroscience
  • Pharmacology
  • Physiology
  • Plant Biology
  • Population Biology
  • Psychological and Cognitive Sciences
  • Sustainability Science
  • Systems Biology
Research Article

Competition between collective and individual dynamics

Sébastian Grauwin, Eric Bertin, Rémi Lemoy, and Pablo Jensen
PNAS December 8, 2009 106 (49) 20622-20626; https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0906263106
Sébastian Grauwin
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
Eric Bertin
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
Rémi Lemoy
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
Pablo Jensen
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  • For correspondence: pablo.jensen@ens-lyon.fr
  1. Edited by H. Eugene Stanley, Boston University, Boston, MA, and approved October 19, 2009 (received for review June 10, 2009)

  • Article
  • Figures & SI
  • Info & Metrics
  • PDF
Loading

Abstract

Linking microscopic and macroscopic behavior is at the heart of many natural and social sciences. This apparent similarity conceals essential differences across disciplines: Although physical particles are assumed to optimize the global energy, economic agents maximize their own utility. Here, we solve exactly a Schelling-like segregation model, which interpolates continuously between cooperative and individual dynamics. We show that increasing the degree of cooperativity induces a qualitative transition from a segregated phase of low utility toward a mixed phase of high utility. By introducing a simple function that links the individual and global levels, we pave the way to a rigorous approach of a wide class of systems, where dynamics are governed by individual strategies.

  • socioeconomy
  • statistical physics
  • segregation
  • phase transition
  • coordination

The intricate relations between the individual and collective levels are at the heart of many natural and social sciences. Different disciplines wonder how atoms combine to form solids (1, 2), neurons give rise to consciousness (3, 4), or individuals shape societies (5, 6). However, scientific fields assume distinct points of view for defining the “normal”, or “equilibrium”, aggregated state. Physics looks at the collective level, selecting the configurations that minimize the global free energy (2). In contrast, economic agents behave in a selfish way, and equilibrium is attained when no agent can increase its own satisfaction (7). Although similar at first sight, the two approaches lead to radically different outcomes.

In this paper, we illustrate the differences between collective and individual dynamics on an exactly solvable model similar to Schelling's segregation model (8). The model considers individual agents that prefer a mixed environment, with dynamics that lead to segregated or mixed patterns at the global level. A “tax” parameter monitors continuously the agents' degree of altruism or cooperativity, i.e., their consideration of the global welfare. At high degrees of cooperativity, the system is in a mixed phase of maximal utility. As the altruism parameter is decreased, a phase transition occurs, leading to segregation. In this phase, the agents' utilities remain low, in spite of continuous efforts to maximize their satisfaction. This paradoxical result of Schelling's segregation model (8) has generated an abundant literature. Many papers have simulated how the global state depends on specific individual utility functions, as reviewed by ref. 9. There have been attempts at solving Schelling's model analytically, in order to provide more general results (10, 11). However, these approaches are limited to specific utility functions. More recently, physicists have tried to use a statistical physics approach to understand the segregation transition (12 –14). The idea seems promising because statistical physics has successfully bridged the micro–macro gap for physical systems governed by collective dynamics. However, progress was slowed by lack of an appropriate framework allowing for individual dynamics (12). In this paper, we introduce a rigorous generalization of the physicist's free energy, which includes individual dynamics. By introducing a “link” state function that is maximized in the stationary state, we pave the way to analytical treatments of a much wider class of systems where dynamics are governed by individual strategies. Applied to the above Schelling-like segregation model, this approach offers a quantitative solution for very general utility functions.

Model

Our model represents in a schematic way the dynamics of residential moves in a city. For simplicity, we include one type of agent, but our results can readily be generalized to deal with agents of two “colors,” as in the original Schelling model (8) (see Discussion and SI Appendix). The city is divided into Q blocks (Q ≫ 1), each block containing H cells or flats (Fig. 1). We assume that each cell can contain at most one agent, so that the number n q of agents in a given block q (q = 1,…,Q) satisfies n q ≤ H, and we introduce the density of agents ρq = n q/H. Each agent has the same utility function u(ρq), which describes the degree of satisfaction concerning the density of the block in which he is living. The collective utility is defined as the total utility of all the agents in the city: U(x) = H∑qρq u(ρq), where x ≡ {ρq} corresponds to the coarse-grained configuration of the city, i.e., the knowledge of the density of each block. For a given x, there is a large number of ways to arrange the agents in the different cells. This number of arrangements is quantified by its logarithm S(x), called the entropy of the configuration x.

Fig. 1.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 1.

Configurations of a city composed of Q = 36 blocks containing each H = 100 cells, with ρ0 = 1/2. (A) Mixed state. Stationary state of the city for m = 0.5, α = 1, and T → 0. Agents are distributed homogeneously between the blocks, each of them having a density of 0.5. (B) Segregated configuration. Stationary state of the city for m = 0.5, α = 0, and T → 0. Agents are gathered on 22 blocks of mean density 0.82, the other blocks being empty. In the original Schelling model (8), each agent has a distinct neighborhood, defined by its eight nearest neighbors. Here, we only keep the essential ingredient of blocks of distinct densities. Our model shows the same qualitative behavior as Schelling's but can be solved exactly, thanks to the partial reduction of the agents' heterogeneity.

The dynamical rule allowing the agents to move from one block to another is the following. At each time step, one picks up at random an agent and a vacant cell. Then the agent moves in that empty cell with probability Embedded Image where x and y are respectively the configurations before and after the move, and G is the gain associated to the proposed move. The positive parameter T is a “temperature” that introduces in a standard way (15) some noise on the decision process. It can be interpreted as the effect of features that are not explicitly included in the utility function but still affect the moving decision (urban facilities, friends, etc.). We write the gain G as Embedded Image where Δu is the variation of the agent's own utility upon moving and ΔU is the variation of the total utility of all agents. The parameter 0 ≤ α ≤ 1 weights the contribution of the other agents' utility variation in the calculation of the gain G, and it can thus be interpreted as a degree of cooperativity (or altruism). For α = 0, the probability to move only depends on the selfish interest of the chosen agent, which corresponds to the spirit of economic models such as Schelling's. When α = 1, the decision to move only depends on the collective utility change, as in physics models. An economical interpretation could be that individual moves are controlled by a central government, via a tax that internalizes all the externalities (more on this in Discussion). Varying α in a continuous way, one can interpolate between the two limiting behaviors of individual and collective dynamics.

Results

We wish to find the stationary probability distribution Π(x) of the microscopic configurations x. If the gain G can be written as G = ΔV ≡ V(y) − V(x), where V(x) is a function of the configuration x, then the dynamics satisfy the detailed balance (16), and the distribution Π(x) is given by Embedded Image with F(x) = V(x) + TS(x) and Z a normalization constant. The entropy has for large H the standard expression S(x) = H∑q s(ρq), with Embedded Image We now need to find the function V(x), if it exists. Given the form in Eq. 2 of G, finding such a function V(x) amounts to finding a “link” function L(x), connecting the individual and collective levels, such that Δu = ΔL. The function V would thus be given by V(x) = (1 − α)L(x) + αU(x). By analogy to the entropy, we assume that L(x) can be written as a sum over the blocks, namely L(x) = H∑qℓ(ρq). Considering a move from a block at density ρ1 to a block at density ρ2, ΔL reduces in the large H limit to ℓ′(ρ2) − ℓ′(ρ1), where ℓ′ is the derivative of ℓ. The condition Δu = ΔL then leads to the identification ℓ′(ρ) = u(ρ), from which the expression of ℓ(ρ) follows: Embedded Image As a result, the function F(x) can be expressed in the large H limit as F(x) = H∑q f(ρq), with a block potential f(ρ) given by Embedded Image

The probability Π(x) is dominated by the configurations x = {ρq} that maximize the sum ∑q f(ρq) under the constraint of a fixed ρ0 = Q −1∑q = 1 Q ρq. To perform this maximization procedure, we follow standard physics methods used in the study of phase transitions [like liquid–vapor coexistence (18)], which can be summarized as follows. If f(ρ) coincides with its concave hull at a given density ρ0, then the state of the city is homogeneous, and all blocks have a density ρ0. Otherwise, a phase separation occurs: Some blocks have a density ρ1 * < ρ0, whereas the others have a density ρ2 * > ρ0 (see SI Appendix).

Interestingly, the potential F = (1 − α)L + αU + TS appears as a generalization of the notion of free energy introduced in physical systems. Mapping the global utility U onto the opposite of the energy of a physical system, it turns out that for α = 1, the maximization of the function U + TS is equivalent to the minimization of the free energy E − TS. For α < 1, the potential F takes into account individual moves through the link function L. Furthermore, the potential F can be calculated for arbitrary utility functions, allowing one to predict analytically the global town state. Such an achievement has thus far eluded individualistic, Schelling-type models, which had to be studied through numerical simulations (9).

To explicitly obtain the equilibrium configurations, one needs to know the specific form of the utility function. To illustrate the dramatic influence of the cooperativity parameter α, we use the asymmetrically peaked utility function (18), which indicates that agents prefer mixed blocks (Fig. 2). The overall town density is fixed at ρ0 = 1/2 to avoid the trivial utility frustration resulting from the impossibility to attain the optimal equilibrium (ρq = 1/2 for all blocks). We also consider for simplicity the limit T → 0 in order to avoid entropy effects. The qualitative behavior of the system is unchanged for ρ0 ≠ 1/2 or for low values of the temperature, as shown in the SI Appendix.

Fig. 2.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 2.

Asymmetrically peaked individual utility as a function of block density. The utility is defined as u(ρ) = 2ρ if ρ ≤ 1/2 and u(ρ) = m + 2(1 − m)(1− ρ) if ρ > 1/2, where 0 < m < 1 is the asymmetry parameter. Agents strictly prefer half-filled neighborhoods (ρ = 1/2). The agents also prefer overcrowded (ρ = 1) neighborhoods to empty ones (ρ = 0).

In the collective case (α = 1), the optimal state corresponds to the configuration that maximizes the global utility, which can be immediately guessed from Fig. 2, namely ρq = 1/2 for all q (Fig. 1 A). On the contrary, in the selfish case (α = 0, Fig. 1 B), maximization of the potential F(x) shows that the town settles in a segregated configuration where a fraction of the blocks are empty and the others have a density ρs > 1/2. Surprisingly, the city settles in this state of low utility in spite of agents' continuous efforts to maximize their own satisfaction. To understand this frustrated configuration, note that the collective equilibrium (ρq = 1/2 for all q) is now an unstable Nash equilibrium at T > 0. The instability can be understood by noting that at T > 0 there is a positive probability that an agent accepts a slight decrease of its utility and leaves a block with density ρq = 1/2. The agents remaining in its former block now have a lower utility and are more likely to leave to go to another ρq = 1/2 block. This departure creates an avalanche that empties the block as each move away further decreases the utility of the remaining agents. This avalanche stops when the stable (Nash) equilibrium, given by the maximum of the potential, is reached. This state corresponds to a spatially inhomogeneous repartition of agents in the city. To understand the transition between mixed and segregated configurations, it is instructive to calculate the values of both the overall utility and the potential for different values of m (at α = 0). For homogeneous towns, for all m, the normalized collective utility is given by U* = U/(ρ0 HQ) = u(ρ0 = 1/2) = 1 and the normalized link function equals L* = L/(ρ0 HQ) = ℓ(ρ0)/ρ0 = 1/2, where ℓ is given in Eq. 5. The values of L* and U* displayed in Table 1 show that the utility of the segregated equilibrium is lower but that its potential is higher, explaining its stability. Note that the gap between the link function values of the homogeneous and segregated configurations increases with m.

View this table:
  • View inline
  • View popup
Table 1.

Characteristics of the segregated equilibrium

This increase helps one understand why the greater the m, the greater the value of tax parameter necessary to reach the homogeneous configuration. Indeed, the segregated states are separated from mixed states by a phase transition at the critical value αc = 1/(3 − 2m), which increases with m (Fig. 3). This transition differs from standard equilibrium phase transitions known in physics, which are most often driven by the competition between energy and entropy. Here, the transition is driven by a competition between the collective and individual components of the agents' dynamics. The unsatisfactory global state of the city can be interpreted, from the economic point of view, as an effect of externalities: By moving to increase its utility, an agent may decrease other agents' utilities without taking this into account. From a standard interpretation in terms of Pigouvian tax (19), one expects that α = 1 is necessary to reach the optimal state because by definition this value internalizes all the externalities the agent causes to the others when moving. Our results show that the optimal state is maintained until much lower tax values are reached (for example, αc = 1/3 at m = 0), a surprising result which deserves further analysis. Another interesting effect is observed for m > 2/3 (Fig. 3). Introducing a small tax has no effect on the overall satisfaction, the utility remaining constant until a threshold level is attained at αt = (3m − 2)/(6 − 5m).

Fig. 3.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 3.

Phase diagram of the global utility as a function of the cooperativity α and the asymmetry m, at T → 0 and ρ0 = 1/2. The average utility per agent U* = U/(ρ0 HQ) is calculated by maximizing the potential F(x) for the peaked utility shown in Fig. 2 (see SI Appendix). The plateau at high values of α corresponds to the mixed phase of optimal utility, which is separated from the segregated state by a phase transition arising at αc = 1/(3 − 2m). The overall picture is qualitatively unchanged for low but finite values of the temperature, (see SI Appendix).

We focused up to now on the zero temperature limit. For low temperatures, the main qualitative conclusions are not modified, as the phase diagram is modified only for extremal values of ρ0 by entropic contributions. At higher temperatures, the city tends to become homogeneous as the effect of “noise” (i.e., of the features that are not described in the model) dominates over the utility associated with the densities of the blocks (see Fig. 4).

Fig. 4.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 4.

Phase diagrams for the asymmetrically peaked individual utility (Fig. 2, with m = 0.8) for different values of T. Increasing the temperature T tends to favor homogeneous states. For small but finite temperatures (roughly T < 0.2), the phase diagram is modified only for extremal values of ρ0, as expected from the entropic term Ts(ρ) = −Tρln ρ − T(1 − ρ)ln(1 − ρ). As T is increased, the whole diagram is affected by the entropic term. Compared with the T = 0 case, the main change is the appearance of a second homogeneous phase for ρ0 < 1/2. Although for ρ0 > 1/2 homogeneity corresponds to the optimal choice for the agents, for ρ0 < 1/2, collective utility is not maximized in a homogeneous city. The city is homogeneous by noise, not by choice. Note that an increase in α tends to reduce this domain, whereas it tends to increase the homogeneous domain for ρ0 > 1/2.

Discussion

In the limit α = 0, our model becomes similar to Schelling's segregation model (8), with two main differences: the existence of two types of agents of two colors and the definition of the agent's neighborhoods. We now show that these additional features do not introduce any essential effect.

Let us start by introducing two types of agents with different “colors” (such as red and green). Simple calculations (see SI Appendix) show that for two species that only care about the density of neighbors of their own color, the block potential Eq. 6 becomes Embedded Image with straightforward notations (for example, u R(ρR) represents the utility of a red agent in a block with a density ρR of red agents). In the more general case of utility functions depending on both the density of similar and dissimilar neighbors, it is also possible to derive a block potential if the utility functions verify a symmetry constraint. This constraint is not very restrictive, in the sense that no qualitative feature of the model is lost when one restrains the study to utilities that verify it (see SI Appendix).

Finding the equilibrium configurations amounts to finding the set {ρqR, ρqG}, which maximizes the potential F(x) = ∑q f(ρqR, ρqG) with the constraints ∑qρqR = Qρ0R and ∑qρqG = Qρ0G, where ρ0G and ρ0R represent, respectively, the overall concentration of green and red agents.

Because of the spatial constraints (the densities of red and green agents in each block q must verify ρqR + ρqG ≤ 1), the “two populations” model cannot formally be reduced to two independent “one population” models. However, the stationary states can still be easily computed. Let us focus once again on the T → 0 limit and suppose, for example, that ρ0R = ρ0G = ρ0/2. The stationary state depends once again on the values of ρ0, m, and α. For low values of α, it can be shown that the system settles in segregated states where each block contains only one kind of agent with a density ρ0 (see Fig. 5 A). For α ≥ αc, the system settles in mixed states where the density of a group in a block is either 0 or 1/2 (see Fig. 5 B). The reader is referred to SI Appendix for more details.

Fig. 5.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 5.

Stationary configurations obtained by simulating the evolution of a city inhabited by an equal number of red and green agents whose preferences are given by the asymmetrically peaked utility function (m = 0.5). The rate of vacant cells (in white) is fixed to 10%. (A and B) The city is divided into blocks of size H = 100. In accordance with the analytic model, a segregated configuration is obtained when α = 0 (A) and a more homogeneous configuration is obtained for α = 1 (B). (C and D) The utility of an agent depends on the local density of similar neighbors computed on the H = 108 nearest cells. Although of different topological nature, a segregated configuration is still obtained for α = 0 (C) and a homogeneous configuration is still obtained for α = 1 (D). In all those simulations, we take T = 0.1. The small amount of noise hence generated, although not changing the nature of the stationary states compared with the case T → 0, conveniently reduces the time of convergence of the system.

We now turn to the difference in agents' neighborhoods. In Schelling's original model, agents' neighbors are defined as their eight nearest neighbors. Our model considers instead predefined blocks of common neighbors. First, it should be noted that there is no decisive argument in favor of either neighborhood definition in terms of the realism of the description of real social neighborhoods. Second, we note that introducing blocks allows for an analytical solution for arbitrary utility functions. This contrasts with the nearest neighbor case, where the best analytical approach solves only a modified model that abandons the individual point of view and is limited to a specific utility function (11). Finally, the simulations presented in Fig. 5 show that the transition from segregated to mixed states is not affected by the choice of the neighborhood's definition. We conclude that the block description is more adapted to this kind of simple modeling, which aims at showing stylized facts as segregation transitions.

Our simple model raises a number of interesting questions about collective or individual points of view. In the purely collective case (α = 1), the stationary state corresponds to the maximization of the average utility, in analogy to the minimization of energy in physics. In the opposite case (α = 0), the stationary state strongly differs from the simple collection of individual optima (20): The optimization strategy based on purely individual dynamics fails, illustrating the unexpected links between micromotives and macrobehavior (21). However, the emergent collective state can be efficiently captured by the maximization of the link function ℓ(ρ) given in Eq. 5, up to constraints in the overall town density. This function intimately connects the individual and global points of view. First, it depends only on the global town configuration (given by the ρq), allowing a relatively simple calculation of the equilibrium. At the same time, it can be interpreted as the sum of the individual marginal utilities gained by agents as they progressively fill the city after leaving a reservoir of zero utility. In the stationary state, a maximal value of the potential L is reached. Therefore, no agent can increase its utility by moving (because Δu = ΔL), consistent with the economists' definition of a Nash equilibrium.

Equilibrium statistical mechanics has developed powerful tools to link the microscopic and macroscopic levels. These tools are limited to physical systems, where dynamics are governed by a global quantity such as the total energy. By introducing a link function, analogous to state functions in thermodynamics or potential functions in game theory (22), we have extended the framework of statistical mechanics to a Schelling-like model. Such an approach paves the way to analytical treatments of a much wider class of systems, where dynamics are governed by individual strategies.

Acknowledgments

We acknowledge interesting discussions with Florence Goffette–Nagot.

Footnotes

  • 1To whom correspondence may be addressed. E-mail: pablo.jensen{at}ens-lyon.fr
  • Author contributions: S.G., E.B., and P.J. designed research; S.G., E.B., R.L., and P.J. performed research; and S.G., E.B., R.L., and P.J. wrote the paper.

  • The authors declare no conflict of interest.

  • This article is a PNAS Direct Submission.

  • This article contains supporting information online at www.pnas.org/cgi/content/full/0906263106/DCSupplemental.

References

  1. ↵
    1. Cotterill R
    (2008) The Cambridge Guide to the Material World (Cambridge Univ Press, New Rochelle, NY).
  2. ↵
    1. Goodstein D
    (1985) States of Matter (Dover, New York).
  3. ↵
    1. Damasio AR
    (1995) The Feeling of What Happens (Harcourt Brace, New York).
  4. ↵
    1. Changeux JP
    (2009) The Physiology of Truth: Neuroscience and Human Knowledge (Belknap Press, Cambridge, MA).
  5. ↵
    1. Strahan W,
    2. Cadell T
    1. Smith A
    (1776) in An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, eds Strahan W, Cadell T (Methuen, London).
  6. ↵
    1. Latour B
    (2007) Reassembling the Social: An Introduction to Actor-Network-Theory (Oxford Univ Press, New York).
  7. ↵
    1. Mas–Colell A,
    2. Whinston MD,
    3. Green JR
    (1995) Microeconomic Theory (Oxford Univ Press, New York).
  8. ↵
    1. Schelling TC
    (1971) Dynamic models of segregation. J Math Sociol 1:143–186.
    OpenUrl
  9. ↵
    1. Clark W,
    2. Fossett M
    (2008) Understanding the social context of the Schelling segregation model. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 105:4109–4114.
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  10. ↵
    1. Pollicott M,
    2. Weiss H
    (2001) The dynamics of Schelling-type segregation models and a nonlinear graph Laplacian variational problem. Adv Appl Math 27:17–40.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  11. ↵
    1. Zhang J
    (2004) Residential segregation in an all-integrationist world. J Econ Behav Org 54:533–550.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  12. ↵
    1. Dall–Asta L,
    2. Castellano C,
    3. Marsili M
    (2008) Statistical physics of the Schelling model of segregation. J Stat Mech Theor Exp, L07002.
  13. ↵
    1. Vinkovic D,
    2. Kirman A
    (2006) A physical analogue of the Schelling model. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 103:19261–19265.
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  14. ↵
    1. Gauvin L,
    2. Vannimenus J,
    3. Nadal J-P
    (2009) Phase diagram of a Schelling segregation model. Eur Phys J B 70:293–304.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  15. ↵
    1. Anderson SP,
    2. De Palma A,
    3. Thisse JF
    (1992) Discrete Choice Theory of Product Differentiation (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA).
  16. ↵
    1. Evans M,
    2. Hanney T
    (2005) Nonequilibrium statistical mechanics of the zero-range process and related models. J Phys Math Gen 38:R195–R240.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
    1. Callen H
    (1985) Thermodynamics and an Introduction to Thermostatistics (Wiley, New York).
  17. ↵
    1. Pancs R,
    2. Vriend N
    (2007) Schelling's spatial proximity model of segregation revisited. J Publ Econ 91:1–24.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  18. ↵
    1. Auerbach A
    (1985) The theory of excess burden and optimal taxation. Handbook Publ Econ 1:61–127.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  19. ↵
    1. Kirman AP
    (1992) Whom or what does the representative individual represent? J Econ Perspect 6:117–136.
    OpenUrl
  20. ↵
    1. Schelling TC
    (1978) Micromotives and Macrobehavior (Norton, New York).
  21. ↵
    1. Monderer D,
    2. Shapley L
    (1996) Potential games. Game Econ Behav 14:124–143.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
View Abstract
Back to top
Article Alerts
Email Article

Thank you for your interest in spreading the word on PNAS.

NOTE: We only request your email address so that the person you are recommending the page to knows that you wanted them to see it, and that it is not junk mail. We do not capture any email address.

Enter multiple addresses on separate lines or separate them with commas.
Competition between collective and individual dynamics
(Your Name) has sent you a message from PNAS
(Your Name) thought you would like to see the PNAS web site.
Citation Tools
Competition between collective and individual dynamics
Sébastian Grauwin, Eric Bertin, Rémi Lemoy, Pablo Jensen
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences Dec 2009, 106 (49) 20622-20626; DOI: 10.1073/pnas.0906263106

Citation Manager Formats

  • BibTeX
  • Bookends
  • EasyBib
  • EndNote (tagged)
  • EndNote 8 (xml)
  • Medlars
  • Mendeley
  • Papers
  • RefWorks Tagged
  • Ref Manager
  • RIS
  • Zotero
Request Permissions
Share
Competition between collective and individual dynamics
Sébastian Grauwin, Eric Bertin, Rémi Lemoy, Pablo Jensen
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences Dec 2009, 106 (49) 20622-20626; DOI: 10.1073/pnas.0906263106
del.icio.us logo Digg logo Reddit logo Twitter logo CiteULike logo Facebook logo Google logo Mendeley logo
  • Tweet Widget
  • Facebook Like
  • Mendeley logo Mendeley
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences: 116 (50)
Current Issue

Submit

Sign up for Article Alerts

Article Classifications

  • Physical Sciences
  • Applied Physical Sciences
  • Social Sciences
  • Economic Sciences

Jump to section

  • Article
    • Abstract
    • Model
    • Results
    • Discussion
    • Acknowledgments
    • Footnotes
    • References
  • Figures & SI
  • Info & Metrics
  • PDF

You May Also be Interested in

News Feature: Getting the world’s fastest cat to breed with speed
Cheetahs once rarely reproduced in captivity. Today, cubs are born every year in zoos. Breeding programs have turned their luck around—but they aren’t done yet.
Image credit: Mehgan Murphy/Smithsonian Conservation Biology Institute.
Adaptations in heart structure and function likely enabled endurance and survival in preindustrial humans. Image courtesy of Pixabay/Skeeze.
Human heart evolved for endurance
Adaptations in heart structure and function likely enabled endurance and survival in preindustrial humans.
Image courtesy of Pixabay/Skeeze.
Viscoelastic carrier fluids enhance retention of fire retardants on wildfire-prone vegetation. Image courtesy of Jesse D. Acosta.
Viscoelastic fluids and wildfire prevention
Viscoelastic carrier fluids enhance retention of fire retardants on wildfire-prone vegetation.
Image courtesy of Jesse D. Acosta.
Water requirements may make desert bird declines more likely in a warming climate. Image courtesy of Sean Peterson (photographer).
Climate change and desert bird collapse
Water requirements may make desert bird declines more likely in a warming climate.
Image courtesy of Sean Peterson (photographer).
QnAs with NAS member and plant biologist Sheng Yang He. Image courtesy of Sheng Yang He.
Featured QnAs
QnAs with NAS member and plant biologist Sheng Yang He
Image courtesy of Sheng Yang He.

Similar Articles

Site Logo
Powered by HighWire
  • Submit Manuscript
  • Twitter
  • Facebook
  • RSS Feeds
  • Email Alerts

Articles

  • Current Issue
  • Latest Articles
  • Archive

PNAS Portals

  • Classics
  • Front Matter
  • Teaching Resources
  • Anthropology
  • Chemistry
  • Physics
  • Sustainability Science

Information

  • Authors
  • Editorial Board
  • Reviewers
  • Press
  • Site Map
  • PNAS Updates

Feedback    Privacy/Legal

Copyright © 2019 National Academy of Sciences. Online ISSN 1091-6490