Skip to main content

Main menu

  • Home
  • Articles
    • Current
    • Special Feature Articles - Most Recent
    • Special Features
    • Colloquia
    • Collected Articles
    • PNAS Classics
    • List of Issues
  • Front Matter
    • Front Matter Portal
    • Journal Club
  • News
    • For the Press
    • This Week In PNAS
    • PNAS in the News
  • Podcasts
  • Authors
    • Information for Authors
    • Editorial and Journal Policies
    • Submission Procedures
    • Fees and Licenses
  • Submit
  • Submit
  • About
    • Editorial Board
    • PNAS Staff
    • FAQ
    • Accessibility Statement
    • Rights and Permissions
    • Site Map
  • Contact
  • Journal Club
  • Subscribe
    • Subscription Rates
    • Subscriptions FAQ
    • Open Access
    • Recommend PNAS to Your Librarian

User menu

  • Log in
  • My Cart

Search

  • Advanced search
Home
Home
  • Log in
  • My Cart

Advanced Search

  • Home
  • Articles
    • Current
    • Special Feature Articles - Most Recent
    • Special Features
    • Colloquia
    • Collected Articles
    • PNAS Classics
    • List of Issues
  • Front Matter
    • Front Matter Portal
    • Journal Club
  • News
    • For the Press
    • This Week In PNAS
    • PNAS in the News
  • Podcasts
  • Authors
    • Information for Authors
    • Editorial and Journal Policies
    • Submission Procedures
    • Fees and Licenses
  • Submit
Research Article

Network structure of production

Enghin Atalay, Ali Hortaçsu, James Roberts, and Chad Syverson
  1. aDepartment of Economics, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL 60637;
  2. bDepartment of Economics, Duke University, Durham, NC 27708; and
  3. cBooth School of Business, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL 60637

See allHide authors and affiliations

PNAS March 29, 2011 108 (13) 5199-5202; https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1015564108
Enghin Atalay
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
Ali Hortaçsu
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  • For correspondence: hortacsu@uchicago.edu
James Roberts
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
Chad Syverson
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  1. Edited by Lars Peter Hansen, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL, and approved February 2, 2011 (received for review October 15, 2010)

  • Article
  • Figures & SI
  • Info & Metrics
  • PDF
Loading

Abstract

Complex social networks have received increasing attention from researchers. Recent work has focused on mechanisms that produce scale-free networks. We theoretically and empirically characterize the buyer–supplier network of the US economy and find that purely scale-free models have trouble matching key attributes of the network. We construct an alternative model that incorporates realistic features of firms’ buyer–supplier relationships and estimate the model’s parameters using microdata on firms’ self-reported customers. This alternative framework is better able to match the attributes of the actual economic network and aids in further understanding several important economic phenomena.

  • industrial organization
  • network dynamics

Firms’ interconnections through buyer–supplier relationships affect economic phenomena ranging from the spread of innovative ideas (1) to the transmission of economic shocks (2) to trade patterns (3). Recognizing this, economists have started to pay explicit attention to firm network structures (refs. 4 and 5 and the studies discussed in ref. 6). However, no one has theoretically or empirically characterized the actual firm network structure in any large economy. Here, we establish basic features of the buyer–supplier network of firms in the United States and develop a model of firm birth, death, and input–output link formation that closely replicates the observed network.

Earlier research modeled the formation and structure of complex social networks more broadly. Examples include links on the worldwide web (7), job-search networks (8), and friendships (9); refs. 10 and 11 have recent surveys. Much of this recent work was spurred by seminal work (7) documenting the scale-free nature of many networks. We show, however, that scale-free network models miss important elements of the US economy’s firm network. In particular, the fat-tail nature of scale-free networks overstates the connectivity of the economy’s most central vertices—that is, the most vertically interconnected firms. At the same time, it overpredicts the number of minimally connected firms.

We propose an alternative model of network formation that better matches the connectivity distribution of US firms. Following the model in ref. 12, our model adds processes for vertex (firm) death and reattachment of those edges (buyer–supplier relationships) among surviving firms. It also allows new edges to be formed through a mix of the preferential attachment mechanisms emblematic of scale-free network models (where new edges are more likely to be formed with vertices that already have more edges) and random attachment (similar to that in ref. 13). Although these extensions are sparsely parameterized, they considerably extend the ability of network formation models to match observed firm network structures. Importantly, they also embody realistic features of the actual firm network: firms often go out of business, and many suppliers actively prefer to work with less-connected downstream firms because of product specialization and long-term contracting issues. We estimate our model’s parameters using microdata on firms’ self-reported buyer–supplier links. This approach shows that the model, despite being estimated using variation at the micro level, is able to closely match the macro distribution of firm connectedness. Using the model, we can predict economic phenomena such as the transmission of economic shocks throughout the network.

Modeling the In-Degree Distribution

Denote N(t) as the number of vertices, which represent firms, in the network at any time t. Each vertex has an in-degree, k; these k edges represent links with each of the suppliers of the firm. Let n(k, t) denote the number of vertices of in-degree k at time t [∑k n(k, t) = N(t)]. Let Embedded Image be the average number of customers (or suppliers) per firm. At each t, three distinct processes act to change the network structure.

  • i) Death of existing firms. Firms uniformly and permanently exit the network with probability q.* This results in the destruction of q(2 − q)N(t)m(t) edges.† Of these destroyed edges, q(1 − q)N(t)m(t) have the receiving vertex survive to the next period.

  • ii) Rewiring of surviving firms. q(1 − q)N(t)m(t) of the edges that were destroyed because of firm death are reformed among surviving vertices as firms attempt to replace existing customers. We assume a fraction r of these rewired edges is allocated uniformly (that is, with probability Embedded Image) across each of the surviving vertices. The remaining fraction of 1 − r edges is allocated by preferential attachment: a vertex with k surviving edges receives a rewired edge from another surviving firm with probability Embedded Image, the vertex’s share of surviving edges in the network.

  • iii) Birth of new firms. (g + q)N(t) new vertices enter the network, each forming m(t) edges. A fraction δ of these edges extends to existing firms. A fraction 1 − r is allocated by a preferential attachment rule, whereas the other r of the δ(q + g)N(t)m(t) edges is allocated uniformly across the existing vertices. Finally, 1 – δ of the (q + g)N(t)m(t) new edges is assumed to be distributed uniformly and independently among the other (q + g)N(t) new firms that entered at the same time. Note that, because q is the average probability of vertex death, g is the net average growth rate of the number of vertices in the network.

The structure of a network with these growth and decay features in which edges and nodes appear and disappear probabilistically can be approximated by the following partial differential equation (12) (Eq. 1):Embedded Image

γ(k, t) is the in-degree growth rate of a vertex, and β(k, t) is the in-degree distribution of entering vertices. We derive these expressions below. This mass balance equation says that the internally accumulated change in the network’s in-degree structure must equal the net change caused by birth and death.

The expressions β(k, t) and γ(k, t) are determined as follows. Recall that (q + g)N(t)(1 – δ)m(t) new edges are distributed uniformly among the (q + g)N(t) new firms at t. Because these edges are allocated independently, the in-degree distribution for an entering vertex is BinomialEmbedded Image. To obtain a continuous approximation to this distribution, we use the exponential Embedded Image.

Each period, the in-degree of a vertex can change in one of three ways. It can lose edges because of the exit of other vertices, receive new edges from existing vertices through the rewiring process, or form edges with new vertices. Putting the three processes together, a vertex of in-degree k adds, on average, Embedded Image edges per time step.

Let Embedded Image be the density of firms with in-degree k at time t. Divide Eq. 1 by N(t) and rearrange (Eq. 2):Embedded Image

We want to solve for stationary distribution of p(k, t). Letting Embedded Image and substituting our expressions for γ(k, t) and β(k, t) into Eq. 2 yields (Eq. 3)Embedded Image

The solution to Eq. 3 takes the following form (Eq. 4):Embedded Imagewhere Embedded Image, and Γ is the upper incomplete γ-function.‡

It is useful to compare this model to the predicted in-degree distribution of a pure preferential attachment model, as in ref. 7. The cumulative distribution function of vertex in-degree is Embedded Image, and the slope of log(1 − F(k)) vs. log(k) is constant. Departures from a linear relationship in our model occur when δ decreases or r increases. Intuitively, for smaller δ or larger r, a larger fraction of the edges is allocated to vertices independent of the vertices’ in-degrees.

We will use our microdata on buyer–supplier relationships to estimate the model’s parameters, solve for the implied steady-state in-degree distribution using Eq. 4, and compare the result with the observed distribution in the data.

Empirical Approach and Results

Data.

We estimate the parameters of our model using yearly firm-level data from the Compustat database. These data contain accounting and operations information compiled from publicly listed firms’ financial disclosures. Our firm panel spans from 1979 to 2007 and contains a total of over 39,000 firm-year observations. The longitudinal nature of the data lets us track individual firms’ operations over time. Critically for our use here, Compustat contains firms’ own reports of their major customers in accordance with Financial Accounting Standards No. 131. A major customer is defined as a firm that purchases more than 10% of the reporting seller’s revenue, although firms sometimes also report customers that account for less than this. Although this reporting threshold obviously creates a truncation in the number of edges that we can identify downstream of a firm, they allow us to compile much more comprehensive lists of firms’ suppliers and through this, a firm’s degree of connectedness in the network.

In SI Text, we show that the truncation issue does not affect the shape of the in-degree distribution; we argue that the probability that an edge is observed is similar for edges with a large or small receiving firm. Therefore, for firms that appear as customers in our dataset, the fraction of edges that we miss because of the 10% rule is similar for low and high in-degree firms.

Table 1 shows the 10 most connected firms in our data for the two 5-y intervals at each end of our sample period. The results are intuitive. The early period is dominated by large manufacturers like the Big Three automakers, Boeing, and McDonnell Douglas, the conglomerate GE, large retailers like Sears and JCPenney, and AT&T. By the end of the sample, the shift of US economic activity away from manufacturing and to services (and particularly, health services) during the past several decades is apparent. The Big Three are still in the 10 most connected firms, although at a lower rank. The most connected retailers have changed to Wal-Mart, Home Depot, and Target, Hewlett-Packard is now the most central technology company, and medical goods and service providers Cardinal Health, AmerisourceBergen, and McKesson have entered the top 10.

View this table:
  • View inline
  • View popup
Table 1.

Top 10 firms from 1979 to 1983 and from 2003 to 2007

These basic patterns are reassuring that our measures of firms’ connectedness are meaningful. That said, there are some limitations to the Compustat dataset, primarily that it contains only publicly listed firms and that different firms do not follow uniform listing criteria for their buyers. However, listed firms account for a very large share of private sector gross domestic product and span virtually every sector of the US economy, a span of coverage that few datasets can match.

Estimation.

Our model has five parameters, q, m, r, δ, and g. We use our microdata on buyer–supplier links to estimate their values in the US firm network. Four parameters can be measured directly in the data. The vertex exit rate, q, is 0.24. The average number of edges per vertex, m, is 1.06. The fraction of edges connecting new vertices to previously existing firms, δ, is 0.75, and the average growth rate of the number of vertices in the network, g, is 0.04. The remaining parameter is r, the fraction of edges that are assigned across existing vertices with uniform probability rather than through preferential attachment. This is not directly observable in the data. We can see which links are formed but cannot directly observe their ex ante probability of being assigned to a particular vertex. However, our model gives an expression for the expected probability that a k in-degree vertex received a particular link from another surviving vertex, an observable event. We use this probability expression, Embedded Image, to estimate r using maximum likelihood. We find that r = 0.18.§

Substituting these parameter estimates into Eq. 4 gives us the model’s prediction of the in-degree distribution of the US firm network.

Results.

Fig. 1A overlays the distribution predicted by the preferential attachment model in ref. 7,¶ on the empirical distribution. The line drawn has a slope of −1, with the intercept chosen to provide the best fit to the data. The Pareto distribution predicted by the model has more mass in the right tail than does the actual network: the most central firms in the network (e.g., Wal-Mart, GE, and Cardinal Health) have fewer buyer–supplier links than the model would predict. Furthermore, the Pareto distribution overpredicts the mass of firms that have low in-degrees.‖ Both of these deviations from the actual distribution are potentially important for evaluating the importance of firm interconnectedness. The roles of the most central firms are, of course, the focus of much research. For example, refs. 16–18 study whether—depending on the structure of the network—a shock to one financial institution can cause a systemic crisis. Although the less-connected firms are individually less critical to the operation of the production network, their sheer joint mass makes them an important aggregate force as well.

Fig. 1.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 1.

Model fit. (A) Preferential attachment model, with data for 2005 (squares) and 2006 (triangles). (B) Model of section two (dashed line) and preferential attachment model (solid line), with data for 2005 (squares) and 2006 (triangles).

Fig. 1B adds the predicted in-degree distribution from our model. Its features introduce a curvature in the relationship between log(1 − F(k)) and log(k) that fits the data better than the linear relationship of the standard preferential attachment model. Our model has a direct departure from the preferential attachment mechanism in that a fraction r of the rewired edges and a fraction 1 − δ + δr of the edges from entering vertices are allocated uniformly across existing vertices. The possibility that not all edges are allocated on the “big get bigger” basis of the preferential attachment mechanism helps capture this curvature. As discussed in the Introduction, this departure from preferential attachment captures realistic features of buyer–supplier networks in an economy where product specialization and vertical contracting considerations may reward tight connections between small numbers of vertically connected firms.

We note that we estimate the model’s parameters from the relationships existing within the microdata and then use the model to project the implications of these parameters out to the cumulative distribution function for the network. We do not simply choose the parameters to find the best-fit curve to the cumulative distribution function. Thus, the model is consistent with both the micro- and macroattributes of the buyer–supplier network.

Our model still preserves the feature of pure preferential attachment models that the probability that a firm adds new suppliers is positively and significantly related to its number of vertical links with existing firms. We verify that this property holds in the data using a logistic regression, where the dependent variable is the probability that a new link forms between two vertices in a given year (the full regression results are available in SI Text). A 1-SD increase in the previous in-degree of vertex j is associated with a 0.03% increase in the probability that a new link forms from vertex i to vertex j (the unconditional probability that a new link forms to vertex j from vertex i is 0.26%). However, these results indicate that many other factors affect the probability that two firms are linked. Firms in the same industry are more likely to be linked to one another, and firms that are geographically close to one another are more likely to be linked to one another. The influence of these other factors is not accounted for in a pure preferential attachment model, and this could be one reason why such models miss important empirical features of the observed buyer–supplier network.

One useful application of mapping the network structure is that it facilitates assessment of the US production system’s vulnerability to shocks. Taking as motivation the recent turmoil in the US automotive industry, we consider the effects of a negative shock to the Big Three auto manufacturers. Fig. 2 shows the 2006 firm network, with the Big Three in red, their immediate suppliers in orange, and all other firms in gray.** The Big Three were responsible for $82 billion dollars in purchases from their suppliers in 2006. Assuming a 45% drop in the Big Three’s purchases (commensurate with their drop in unit sales during 2007–2009), these immediate suppliers would suffer a short-run loss of business of $37 billion. The network map indicates that this immediate spillover impact would affect a substantial but not overwhelming portion of the production network.

Fig. 2.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 2.

Buyer–supplier network in 2006. GM, Ford, and Chrysler are colored red. Their suppliers are colored orange. All other firms are gray.

Conclusion

We have theoretically and empirically characterized the buyer–supplier network of the US economy. Scale-free frameworks that have seen increasing use in modeling social networks have trouble matching the network’s empirical in-degree distribution. We propose an alternative model that parsimoniously incorporates realistic features of firms’ buyer–supplier relationships. Estimating the model from microdata on firms’ self-reported customers, we find that our alternative framework is better able to match the attributes of the actual economic network.

Besides its obvious connection to other work on social networks, we see this research as also being related to investigations into the firm-size distribution (15, 19–22). Those investigations have tied features of firm growth to issues of broader economic importance, such as the ability (or inability) of the macroeconomy to absorb idiosyncratic shocks. An application of the current paper’s framework, which is a topic also considered in ref. 23, is to explore the potentially more direct roles that firm connectedness might play in explaining such issues.

Footnotes

  • ↵1To whom correspondence should be addressed. E-mail: hortacsu{at}uchicago.edu.
  • Author contributions: E.A., A.H., J.R., and C.S. designed research, performed research, analyzed data, and wrote the paper.

  • The authors declare no conflict of interest.

  • This article is a PNAS Direct Submission.

  • ↵*This exit process can be extended to allow for the probability of exit to depend on a vertex’s degree of connectivity, although this considerably complicates the solution.

  • ↵†There are qN(t)m(t) edges that have the sending vertex exit the network, qN(t)m(t) edges that have the receiving vertex exit the network, and q2N(t)m(t) edges that have both the receiving and sending vertex exit the network. Combining these terms, there are (2q – q2)N(t)m(t) edges that are destroyed each period.

  • ↵‡The upper incomplete γ-function is given by Embedded Image. The limit of Γ(a, x) as x → ∞ is 0.

  • ↵§Our estimate of r is the maximand of Embedded Image.

  • ↵¶Refs. 14 and 15 also propose models of city and firm growth, respectively, that generate this predicted distribution.

  • ↵‖From Fig. 1A, we see that a pure preferential attachment model would predict that 84% of firms reported no major suppliers. In 2005, only 62% of the firms reported no major suppliers.

  • ↵**In Fig. 2, we include only vertices in the giant weakly connected component (the largest subset of firms that are connected to one another).

  • This article contains supporting information online at www.pnas.org/lookup/suppl/doi:10.1073/pnas.1015564108/-/DCSupplemental.

References

  1. ↵
    1. Javorcik BS
    (2004) Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity of domestic firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages. Am Econ Rev 94:605–627.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  2. ↵
    1. Conley TG,
    2. Dupor B
    (2003) A spatial analysis of sectoral complementarity. J Polit Econ 111:311–352.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  3. ↵
    1. Hanson GH,
    2. Mataloni RJ,
    3. Slaughter MJ
    (2005) Vertical production networks in multinational firms. Rev Econ Stat 87:664–678.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  4. ↵
    1. Kranton RE,
    2. Minehart DF
    (2001) A theory of buyer–seller networks. Am Econ Rev 91:485–508.
    OpenUrl
  5. ↵
    1. Alfaro L,
    2. Chen M
    (2009) NBER Working Paper No. 15576, The global agglomeration of multinational firms (National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA).
  6. ↵
    1. Jackson MO
    (2008) Social and Economic Networks (Princeton University Press, Princeton).
  7. ↵
    1. Reka A,
    2. Jeong H,
    3. Barabasi AL
    (1999) Diameter of the world wide web. Nature 401:130–131.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  8. ↵
    1. Granovetter MS
    (1995) Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA).
  9. ↵
    1. Currarini S,
    2. Jackson MO,
    3. Pin P
    (2009) An economic model of friendship: Homophily, minorities, and segregation. Econometrica 77:1003–1045.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  10. ↵
    1. Schweitzer F,
    2. et al.
    (2009) Economic networks: The new challenges. Science 325:422–425.
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  11. ↵
    1. Borgatti SP,
    2. Mehra A,
    3. Brass DJ,
    4. Labianca G
    (2009) Network analysis in the social sciences. Science 323:892–895.
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  12. ↵
    1. Saldana J
    (2007) Continuum formalism for modeling growing networks with deletion of nodes. Phys Rev E Stat Nonlin Soft Matter Phys 75:027102.
    OpenUrlCrossRefPubMed
  13. ↵
    1. Jackson MO,
    2. Rogers BW
    (2007) Meeting strangers and friends of friends: How random are social networks? Am Econ Rev 97:890–915.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  14. ↵
    1. Gabaix X
    (1999) Zipf’s law for cities: An explanation. Q J Econ 114:739–767.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  15. ↵
    1. Luttmer EGJ
    (2007) Selection, growth, and the size distribution of firms. Q J Econ 122:1103–1144.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  16. ↵
    1. Allen F,
    2. Gale D
    (2000) Financial contagion. J Polit Econ 108:1–33.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
    1. Freixas X,
    2. Parigi BM,
    3. Rochet JC
    (2000) Systemic risk, interbank relations, and liquidity provision by the central bank. J Money Credit Bank 32:611–638.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  17. ↵
    1. Furfine C
    (2003) Interbank exposures: Quantifying the risk of contagion. J Money Credit Bank 35:111–128.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  18. ↵
    1. Axtell RL
    (2001) Zipf distribution of U.S. firm sizes. Science 293:1818–1820.
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
    1. Cabral LMB,
    2. Mata J
    (2003) On the evolution of the firm size distribution: Facts and theory. Am Econ Rev 93:1075–1090.
    OpenUrlCrossRef
    1. Rossi-Hansberg E,
    2. Wright MLJ
    (2007) Establishment size dynamics in the aggregate economy. Am Econ Rev 97:1639–1666.
    OpenUrl
  19. ↵
    1. Gabaix X
    (2011) The granular origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, in press.
  20. ↵
    1. Carvalho V
    (2010) Aggregate Fluctuations and the Network Structure of Intersectoral Trade (University of Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona).
PreviousNext
Back to top
Article Alerts
Email Article

Thank you for your interest in spreading the word on PNAS.

NOTE: We only request your email address so that the person you are recommending the page to knows that you wanted them to see it, and that it is not junk mail. We do not capture any email address.

Enter multiple addresses on separate lines or separate them with commas.
Network structure of production
(Your Name) has sent you a message from PNAS
(Your Name) thought you would like to see the PNAS web site.
CAPTCHA
This question is for testing whether or not you are a human visitor and to prevent automated spam submissions.
Citation Tools
Network structure of production
Enghin Atalay, Ali Hortaçsu, James Roberts, Chad Syverson
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences Mar 2011, 108 (13) 5199-5202; DOI: 10.1073/pnas.1015564108

Citation Manager Formats

  • BibTeX
  • Bookends
  • EasyBib
  • EndNote (tagged)
  • EndNote 8 (xml)
  • Medlars
  • Mendeley
  • Papers
  • RefWorks Tagged
  • Ref Manager
  • RIS
  • Zotero
Request Permissions
Share
Network structure of production
Enghin Atalay, Ali Hortaçsu, James Roberts, Chad Syverson
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences Mar 2011, 108 (13) 5199-5202; DOI: 10.1073/pnas.1015564108
del.icio.us logo Digg logo Reddit logo Twitter logo CiteULike logo Facebook logo Google logo Mendeley logo
  • Tweet Widget
  • Facebook Like
  • Mendeley logo Mendeley

Article Classifications

  • Social Sciences
  • Economic Sciences
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences: 108 (13)
Table of Contents

Submit

Sign up for Article Alerts

Jump to section

  • Article
    • Abstract
    • Modeling the In-Degree Distribution
    • Empirical Approach and Results
    • Conclusion
    • Footnotes
    • References
  • Figures & SI
  • Info & Metrics
  • PDF

You May Also be Interested in

Water from a faucet fills a glass.
News Feature: How “forever chemicals” might impair the immune system
Researchers are exploring whether these ubiquitous fluorinated molecules might worsen infections or hamper vaccine effectiveness.
Image credit: Shutterstock/Dmitry Naumov.
Reflection of clouds in the still waters of Mono Lake in California.
Inner Workings: Making headway with the mysteries of life’s origins
Recent experiments and simulations are starting to answer some fundamental questions about how life came to be.
Image credit: Shutterstock/Radoslaw Lecyk.
Cave in coastal Kenya with tree growing in the middle.
Journal Club: Small, sharp blades mark shift from Middle to Later Stone Age in coastal Kenya
Archaeologists have long tried to define the transition between the two time periods.
Image credit: Ceri Shipton.
Mouse fibroblast cells. Electron bifurcation reactions keep mammalian cells alive.
Exploring electron bifurcation
Jonathon Yuly, David Beratan, and Peng Zhang investigate how electron bifurcation reactions work.
Listen
Past PodcastsSubscribe
Panda bear hanging in a tree
How horse manure helps giant pandas tolerate cold
A study finds that giant pandas roll in horse manure to increase their cold tolerance.
Image credit: Fuwen Wei.

Similar Articles

Site Logo
Powered by HighWire
  • Submit Manuscript
  • Twitter
  • Facebook
  • RSS Feeds
  • Email Alerts

Articles

  • Current Issue
  • Special Feature Articles – Most Recent
  • List of Issues

PNAS Portals

  • Anthropology
  • Chemistry
  • Classics
  • Front Matter
  • Physics
  • Sustainability Science
  • Teaching Resources

Information

  • Authors
  • Editorial Board
  • Reviewers
  • Subscribers
  • Librarians
  • Press
  • Cozzarelli Prize
  • Site Map
  • PNAS Updates
  • FAQs
  • Accessibility Statement
  • Rights & Permissions
  • About
  • Contact

Feedback    Privacy/Legal

Copyright © 2021 National Academy of Sciences. Online ISSN 1091-6490