Transition to farming more likely for small, conservative groups with property rights, but increased productivity is not essential
- aResearch Department of Genetics, Evolution, & Environment, University College London, London, WC1E 6BT, United Kingdom;
- bCentre for Mathematics, Physics, and Engineering in the Life Sciences and Experimental Biology, University College London, London, WC1E 6BT, United Kingdom;
- cInstitute of Archaeology, University College London, London, WC1H 0PY, United Kingdom
See allHide authors and affiliations
Edited by Bruce P. Winterhalder, University of California, Davis, CA, and accepted by the Editorial Board September 19, 2015 (received for review June 21, 2015)

Significance
The Neolithic revolution was one of the most influential events in human history, but why and how it occurred are still not fully understood. To try to infer what may have happened, mathematical models have been developed. We describe and implement a method of parameter space exploration when ideal outcomes of a model are known. This method is applied to a published agent-based model for the Neolithic transition, revealing previously unidentified parameter interactions, sensitivities, and complexities. Our results highlight the importance of group structuring, group size, conservatism, and farming-friendly property rights, for the switch to farming around 12,000 years ago. We also find that, although advantageous, it is not essential that farming productivity is greater than foraging productivity.
Abstract
Theories for the origins of agriculture are still debated, with a range of different explanations offered. Computational models can be used to test these theories and explore new hypotheses; Bowles and Choi [Bowles S, Choi J-K (2013) Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 110(22):8830–8835] have developed one such model. Their model shows the coevolution of farming and farming-friendly property rights, and by including climate variability, replicates the timings for the emergence of these events seen in the archaeological record. Because the processes modeled occurred a long time ago, it can be difficult to justify exact parameter values; hence, we propose a fitting to idealized outcomes (FIO) method to explore the model’s parameter space in more detail. We have replicated the model of Bowles and Choi, and used the FIO method to identify complexities and interactions of the model previously unidentified. Our results indicate that the key parameters for the emergence of farming are group structuring, group size, conservatism, and farming-friendly property rights (lending further support to Bowles and Choi’s original proposal). We also find that although advantageous, it is not essential that farming productivity be greater than foraging productivity for farming to emerge. In addition, we highlight how model behaviors can be missed when gauging parameter sensitivity via a fix-all-but-one variation approach.
After around 190,000 y of anatomically modern humans living as hunter-gatherers, societies began to make a transition to agricultural subsistence systems. These transitions are thought to have occurred independently in several regions of the world between 11,500 and 3,500 y before present (yBP) (1), and farming has spread to most of the world from these centers. This transition had major impacts on human demography, evolution, diet, health, culture, technology, and social inequality (2⇓⇓–5). It is generally agreed that there are at least three separate regions around the world where agriculture originated independently: the Fertile Crescent, Mesoamerica, and China (1, 2, 5). There is also growing evidence for additional independent origins of domestication, which include the eastern United States, the Andes, the Central and South America tropics, New Guinea, West Africa, and southern and northern India (5).
A range of different explanations for the development of agriculture have been proposed, including some based on affluence and social competition [e.g., via feasting (6)] and others based on stress [e.g., because of population pressure (7) or climate changes (8)]; some propose revolution (e.g., 9), and some suggest changes were made consciously (e.g., 10), whereas others argue changes were made unconsciously (e.g., 11) (1). Whereas the long-term advantages of farming are clear in that it is a strategy that has generally led to increased carrying capacities and greater reproductive successes when adopted (12), the short-term fitness payoffs are less obvious, and it is increasingly recognized that key changes in social institutions would have been necessary (13).
Computational Approaches
Investigating the reasons behind the transition to agriculture is problematic because modern ethnographic data may not be informative on ancient population dynamics, and the material culture record is sparse and only weakly informative on social aspects of the transition. Furthermore, the appearance of domestication traits in various species is likely to postdate their initial cultivation or management, sometimes by some considerable margin (14). In this context, computational models can be helpful in exploring the ecological and social conditions necessary for the transition to agriculture. There are many examples of such models [e.g., 13, 15⇓⇓⇓⇓⇓⇓–22; also the modeling review by Baker et al. (23) and discussion of modeling approaches by Gerbault et al. (24)], which, together, have explored most of the major hypotheses for the origins of agriculture (most notably, climate and population pressure).
Bowles and Choi Model
It has been argued that during the transition to agriculture, the institution of private property emerged (25⇓–27). This idea led Bowles and Choi (13) to hypothesize that the advent of farming was impossible without farming-friendly property rights, and vice versa. Furthermore, they posit that farming was not suddenly invented and then adopted because it was a “better way to make a living” (13) but, instead, that it was only due to particular rare (and perhaps coincidental) environmental and social conditions that it became established. To study these hypotheses, an agent-based model was developed (henceforth referred to as the Bowles and Choi model), calibrated with a proxy of climate volatility [the 18O/16O ratio in the North Greenland Ice Core Project (NGRIP) ice core (28⇓⇓–31)]. Their simulations show that farming and farming-friendly property rights can coevolve with approximately the same timings and magnitude as indicated in the archaeological record.
The Bowles and Choi model (13) is based on 600 agents (the hypothesized size of “a late Pleistocene ethnolinguistic unit”), separated into groups of 20 (the size of “forager bands or small villages”). Agents have two types of strategies: They can be farmers or foragers (their “technology strategy”), and they can have a “behavioral” strategy, whereby they can be a sharer, a bourgeois, or a civic (explained later). The model can be split into five sections: within-group interactions, between-group interactions, cultural updating, behavioral experimentation, and migration. All simulations start with a population of civic foragers, representing what may be expected in the late Pleistocene on the basis of generalizations from hunter-gatherer ethnographies (32).
First, agents obtain their payoffs by foraging or farming. The productivity of foraging,
With a probability
Next, agents are assigned a cultural model for both strategies. Cultural models are generally chosen from within the same group, with the exception of the loser of a between-group interaction, where cultural models are chosen from the winning group. Cultural models are more likely to be from the predominant type of strategy, with the probability that a sharer, bourgeois, or civic is chosen as the cultural model as, respectively,
The last stages in the model are behavioral experimentation, where agents will randomly change their strategies with probability ε, and migration, where agents migrate from their group with probability m and are randomly assigned to another group.
Bowles and Choi (13) ran 1,000 simulations of their model over 2,075 iterations (41,500 y) and recorded the percentage of simulations at each iteration that had more than 50% bourgeois farmers. Their results (Fig. 1) show a small increase in the number of bourgeois farmers around 15,000–13,000 yBP; this small increase is noted to coincide with short-lived experiments in sedentism and storage seen in the Natufian culture. After around 11,000 yBP, there is a steady increase in the number of majority bourgeois farmer simulations, fitting with evidence that independent origins occurred after this point in all of the well-studied regions. For any given year, there are always less than 31 of the 1,000 simulations with a bourgeois farmer majority.
Range (light green), interquartile range (middle green), and median (dark green) of the percentage of metapopulations (1,000 simulations) with a majority of bourgeois farmers at each time point when running our interpretation of the model 1,000 times. Bowles and Choi’s result (13) is shown in black (reproduced from ref. 13).
Fitting to Idealized Outcomes
Choosing default or initial parameter values in computational models can be difficult, because well-evidenced values are not always available. Furthermore, testing a model’s sensitivity to a known range of parameter values can be complicated when there are many parameters. Usually parameters are varied one-by-one while keeping the others at their default values; however, this approach will overlook most interactions between parameters, and poses problems in choosing realistic default values.
Bowles and Choi (13) test the robustness of their model by varying parameters one-by-one, and show that varying parameters through plausible values gives the same outcome as the result with the default parameters, although with changeable magnitudes (SI Appendix, section S3). We expanded on this analysis by running the model
Model parameters, their default value used in the Bowles and Choi model, and the range of values sampled from in the FIO analysis if applicable
Results
Of the
Relative frequency plots of parameter values for different top slices of the 1.2 × 107 simulations (top 1% in green, top 0.5% in blue, and top 0.1% in black). The vertical dashed lines show the default values chosen by Bowles and Choi (13). For example, the panel for the level of conformism (η) shows that values of η around 1 typically generate the highest number of farmers and that there are the fewest simulations with high numbers of farmers when η = 0. Statistical differences between the distribution of the top 1% of simulations and a uniform distribution for each of the parameters are given in SI Appendix, Table S3.
Spearman’s rank correlation coefficients, ρ, between parameter values and the number of farmers in different top slices of the 1.2 × 107 simulations
Parameter interactions, as indicated by correlations between pairs of parameters in the top 1%, 0.5%, and 0.1% of simulations, are shown in Fig. 3 (coefficients are given in SI Appendix, Table S4). The largest of these correlations were between
Eight significant largely (|ρ| > 0.1) correlated pairs of parameters in the top 1% of the 1.2 × 107 simulations. These plots are broken down into all of the top 1% simulations (green, blue and black points), top 0.5% (blue and black points), and top 0.1% (black points). For ease of interpretation, a small amount of width has been added to the y coordinates of the first three panels, and points plotted randomly within these widths.
Relationship between behavioral experimentation (ε) and the number of farmers for simulations with different numbers of groups (g): g = 2 (Left), g = 30 (Middle), and g = 300 (Right) (each point represents one simulation). Thus, when groups are largest (g = 2), there are no simulations with a high proportion of farmers (g >> 300); when groups are midsized (g = 30), there are some; and when groups are smallest (g = 300), there are many. Furthermore, the highest proportion of farmers occurs in simulations where behavioral experimentation is low and groups are small. These plots for all group sizes considered are shown in SI Appendix, Fig. S6.
Ratio of farming productivity to foraging productivity (Va/Vh) and the number of farmers in all 1.2 × 107 simulations; a log10 (Va/Vh) scale is used. The vertical red line shows when the ratio is 1 (i.e., Va = Vh), and the horizontal red line shows the boundary between majority farming and majority foraging simulations. Hence, there are some simulations with a majority of farmers when Va < Vh (top left quadrant).
Discussion
Our analysis has highlighted that the parameters
Structuring.
Our work has highlighted the relationship between the number of groups (
Conservatism.
Another finding of this work is that to generate large numbers of farmers or foragers, behavioral experimentation (
Property Rights.
Our analysis lends further support to the conclusion by Bowles and Choi (13) that farming and farming-friendly property rights can coevolve. One illustration of this support is that although our simulations allowed there to be no property rights (which is when farming property is always contested,
Ratio of the Productivity of Farming to Foraging.
We have also seen that the productivity-of-farming to productivity-of-foraging ratio (
Cost of Conflict and the Level of Conformity, C and η .
The proportion of farmers at 9,000 yBP was moderately sensitive to parameters
For
Insensitive Parameters.
There were a number of parameters whose values were relatively unimportant for the emergence of farming in the model. These parameters were the migration rate (
The probability of migration between groups also makes little difference to the emergence of farming. Perhaps in this model, intergroup cultural updating drives the mixing of different strategies in the population, and so migration among well-mixed groups will not introduce new strategies into groups.
Assumptions and Caveats.
As with all models, there are many assumptions and simplifications in the Bowles and Choi model (13). For example, would cultural updating be likely to occur for every agent at each iteration, would an individual’s technology be as binary as “farmer” or “forager,” and is it likely that foraging and farming productivity are independent of one another?
Whereas the Bowles and Choi model (13) and the analyses presented here are primarily concerned with the initial establishment of farming groups, other factors are likely to have influenced farming’s growth, sustainability, geographical spread, and archaeological visibility. These factors include the availability of suitable plant and animal species for domestication, other local climate and ecological factors, and technological innovations, all of which are likely to affect the relative productivity of farming (
An issue with our approach is making sure that enough simulations were collected, because insufficient simulations can result in poor assessment of model behavior. However, because the relative frequency plots in Fig. 2 do not change greatly with more narrow top slices, we are confident that running more simulations would have only smoothed these plots, rather than supporting different interpretations. Because this approach does not fit to empirical data, there could be another issue in finding what the “idealized outcome” should be. If there are multiple possibilities, as many as possible should be tested. In the case of this work, we found that using various other possible idealized outcomes (number of bourgeois farmers at 9,000 yBP, number of farmers at 0 yBP, and minimum and average number of farmers between 0 and 9,000 yBP) made very little difference to our overall results (SI Appendix, section S4). Furthermore, it is important to pick parameters from a sensible range of values. If the range covers unrealistic values, there will be unnecessary simulations; on the other hand, if the range does not cover all of the realistic values, there could be unseen trends. We have erred on the side of caution; most of our parameter ranges cover all plausible values (parameter ranges are justified in Methods and SI Appendix, section S7).
Conclusion
Here, we have replicated the results of the Bowles and Choi model (13) and implemented an FIO method to explore the parameter space and parameter interactions of this model. To our knowledge, this approach has not been used in archaeological modeling. We have also been able to hypothesize that a number of elements are key for the emergence of farming. These elements are as follows: a population structured into groups, small (but not too small) group sizes, a very low amount of behavioral experimentation, and the presence of farming-friendly property rights. We also found that although it is beneficial for farming when its productivity is greater than the productivity of foraging, it is not essential for its emergence; this result is consistent with previous findings (38). Additionally, our results indicate that costly conflicts within the groups, and high levels of conformity when groups are culturally updating, result in less farming. Furthermore, we find that migration rate and the likelihood and intensity of between-group conflicts are unimportant for the emergence of farming in this model.
To an extent, our analyses contradict the robustness checks reported by Bowles and Choi (13) and reveal parameter complexities and interactions previously unrecognized. They have also allowed us to examine the effects of simultaneously varying parameters, which was not possible using the fix-all-but-one parameter approach. In comparison to Bowles and Choi’s robustness checks (summarized in SI Appendix, section S3), the small range of variations in
The findings from this analysis highlight key conditions for the origins of agriculture, which should be investigated in more detail in future studies (e.g., asking whether groups were small during the transition to agriculture). Our work highlights the problems of the fix-all-but-one parameter approach, and we hope it serves as an example of this type of parameter analysis in the field of computational modeling in archaeology as a means of exploring past processes.
Methods
Replication.
We first attempted to translate the published description of the Bowles and Choi model (13) to replicate their result. Our simulation code was written in C++ and is available on request. Several small errors were identified and corrected after discussion with Bowles and Choi (outlined in SI Appendix, section S2). Following these clarifications and using some of their code for the within-group interactions, we were essentially able to replicate their published results using the default parameter values.
To look at the variability in our results, we ran the model
Parameter Randomization and Ranking Simulations.
We varied the following parameters from the Bowles and Choi model (13):
Next, we ran simulations with parameter sets that were randomly chosen from the ranges discussed above. These simulations were then ranked on how close they are to an idealized outcome. Archaeological evidence indicates that farming in the Near East had become established by the Late/Final Pre-Pottery Neolithic (9,500 to 8,800 yBP) (e.g., ref. 34), hence we ranked our simulations based on the number of farmers they have at 9,000 yBP, where the highest would be classified as the idealized outcome. This number stays roughly the same from 9000 to 0 yBP (SI Appendix, section S4); thus, our results can be applied other origins of farming in different regions of the world [because the Near East was the earliest (1)]. Note that we considered the number of farmers rather than bourgeois farmers in this analysis, although this difference has little impact on the results (SI Appendix, section S4). After running these simulations, the next step was to identify trends in the parameter values of the top simulations and correlations between closeness-of-fit rank order and parameter value.
Acknowledgments
We thank Samuel Bowles and Jung-Kyoo Choi for their invaluable and detailed correspondence during our replication of their model. Thanks to the Molecular and Cultural Evolution (MACE) laboratory, the Centre for Mathematics, Physics, and Engineering in the Life Sciences and Experimental Biology (CoMPLEX), and Peter Bentley for their ongoing advice and support. We also thank the editor and two anonymous reviewers for their helpful and comprehensive comments and suggestions. This study was supported by funding from the Engineering and Physical Sciences Research Council (awarded to E.M.G. through University College London CoMPLEX).
Footnotes
- ↵1To whom correspondence should be addressed. Email: e.gallagher.12{at}ucl.ac.uk.
Author contributions: E.M.G., S.J.S., and M.G.T. designed research; E.M.G. performed research; E.M.G. and M.G.T. contributed new reagents/analytic tools; E.M.G., S.J.S., and M.G.T. analyzed data; and E.M.G., S.J.S., and M.G.T. wrote the paper.
The authors declare no conflict of interest.
This article is a PNAS Direct Submission. B.P.W. is a guest editor invited by the Editorial Board.
This article contains supporting information online at www.pnas.org/lookup/suppl/doi:10.1073/pnas.1511870112/-/DCSupplemental.
References
- ↵.
- Bellwood P
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵.
- Fuller DQ
- ↵
- ↵.
- Cohen MN
- ↵
- ↵.
- Cauvin J
- ↵
- ↵.
- Rindos D
- ↵.
- Bocquet-Appel J-P
- ↵.
- Bowles S,
- Choi J-K
- ↵.
- Zeder MA
- ↵.
- Flannery KV
- Reynolds RG
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵.
- Gerbault P, et al.
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵.
- Gintis H
- Kaplan H,
- Gurven M,
- Hill K,
- Hurtado AM
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵.
- Nosenzo D,
- Quercia S,
- Sefton M
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵.
- Bowles S
- ↵.
- Fry DP
- Ferguson RB
- ↵
Citation Manager Formats
Article Classifications
- Social Sciences
- Anthropology