New Research In
Physical Sciences
Social Sciences
Featured Portals
Articles by Topic
Biological Sciences
Featured Portals
Articles by Topic
- Agricultural Sciences
- Anthropology
- Applied Biological Sciences
- Biochemistry
- Biophysics and Computational Biology
- Cell Biology
- Developmental Biology
- Ecology
- Environmental Sciences
- Evolution
- Genetics
- Immunology and Inflammation
- Medical Sciences
- Microbiology
- Neuroscience
- Pharmacology
- Physiology
- Plant Biology
- Population Biology
- Psychological and Cognitive Sciences
- Sustainability Science
- Systems Biology
Emergence of communities and diversity in social networks
Contributed by H. Eugene Stanley, December 27, 2016 (sent for review March 14, 2016; reviewed by Alex Arenas and David G. Rand)

Significance
Understanding how communities emerge is a fundamental problem in social and economic systems. Here, we experimentally explore the emergence of communities in social networks, using the ultimatum game as a paradigm for capturing individual interactions. We find the emergence of diverse communities in static networks is the result of the local interaction between responders with inherent heterogeneity and rational proposers in which the former act as community leaders. In contrast, communities do not arise in populations with random interactions, suggesting that a static structure stabilizes local communities and social diversity. Our experimental findings deepen our understanding of self-organized communities and of the establishment of social norms associated with game dynamics in social networks.
Abstract
Communities are common in complex networks and play a significant role in the functioning of social, biological, economic, and technological systems. Despite widespread interest in detecting community structures in complex networks and exploring the effect of communities on collective dynamics, a deep understanding of the emergence and prevalence of communities in social networks is still lacking. Addressing this fundamental problem is of paramount importance in understanding, predicting, and controlling a variety of collective behaviors in society. An elusive question is how communities with common internal properties arise in social networks with great individual diversity. Here, we answer this question using the ultimatum game, which has been a paradigm for characterizing altruism and fairness. We experimentally show that stable local communities with different internal agreements emerge spontaneously and induce social diversity into networks, which is in sharp contrast to populations with random interactions. Diverse communities and social norms come from the interaction between responders with inherent heterogeneous demands and rational proposers via local connections, where the former eventually become the community leaders. This result indicates that networks are significant in the emergence and stabilization of communities and social diversity. Our experimental results also provide valuable information about strategies for developing network models and theories of evolutionary games and social dynamics.
Communities are ubiquitous in nature and society (1, 2). Nodes that share common properties often self-organize to form a community. Internet users with common interests, for example, establish online communities and frequently communicate (3). In human society, social communities with distinctive social norms form spontaneously (4). In protein–protein interaction networks, related proteins group together to execute specific functions within a cell (5).
How social communities emerge is one of the fundamental problems in social science. Game theory and models have offered powerful tools for exploring collective behaviors in animal and human society and our evolutionary origins (6⇓⇓⇓–10). Recent theoretical studies found that network structure is significant in the emergence of mutually reinforcing communities among altruistic subjects in social games, such as the prisoner’s dilemma (PD) game, the public goods game (PGG), and the ultimatum game (UG) (11⇓⇓⇓⇓⇓⇓⇓⇓–20). Although some experiments found that cooperation is stabilized in dynamical networks (21⇓⇓–24), stable communities have been rarely observed in laboratory experiments on a variety of static networks (25⇓⇓⇓⇓⇓⇓–32). As a result, how communities emerge in social network systems associated with evolutionary games continues to be an unanswered question.
Social game experiments demonstrate that there is inherent diversity among individuals in cultural and social attitudes toward cooperation, fairness, and punishment (33⇓⇓⇓–37). However, communities with diverse individuals but common internal properties are ubiquitous in society, prompting us to wonder how diverse individuals are able to form communities. Our goal is to answer this question by experimentally exploring the emergence of communities in social networks associated with the UG. This game has been a paradigm for exploring fairness, altruism, and punishment behaviors that challenge the classical game theory assumption that people act in a fully rational and selfish manner (34⇓⇓⇓–38). Thus, exploring social game dynamics allows us to offer a more natural and general interpretation of the self-organization of communities in social networks. In the UG, two players—a proposer and a responder—together decide how to divide a sum of money. The proposer makes an offer that the responder can either accept or reject. Rejection causes both players to get nothing. In a one-shot anonymous interaction if both players are rational and self-interested, the proposer will offer the minimum amount and the responder will accept it to close the deal. However, much experimental evidence has pointed to a different outcome: Responders tend to disregard maximizing their own gains and reject unfair offers (34⇓–36, 38, 39). Although much effort has been devoted to explaining how fairness emerges and the conditions under which fairness becomes a factor (38, 40⇓⇓⇓⇓⇓–46), a comprehensive understanding of the evolution of fairness in social networks via experiments is still lacking.
We conduct laboratory experiments on both homogeneous and heterogeneous networks and find that stable communities with different internal agreements emerge, which leads to social diversity in both types of networks. In contrast, in populations where interactions among players are randomly shuffled after each round, communities and social diversity do not emerge. To explain this phenomenon, we examine individual behaviors and find that proposers tend to be rational and use the (myopic) best-response strategy (43, 47), and responders tend to be irrational and punish unfair acts (34⇓–36, 38, 39). Social norms are established in networks through the local interaction between irrational responders with inherent heterogeneous demands and rational proposers, where responders are the leaders followed by their neighboring proposers. Our work explains how diverse communities and social norms self-organize and provides evidence that network structure is essential to the emergence of communities. Our experiments also make possible the development of network models of altruism, fairness, and cooperation in networked populations.
Results
We conduct four groups of experiments with two treatment groups (T1 and T2) and two control groups (C1 and C2) (Materials and Methods). In T1 and T2 there is a static network structure among the players, a regular bipartite network for T1, and a random bipartite network for T2. In C1 and C2 the interactions among the players constantly change. Each subject plays a single unchanging role, either proposer or responder. We focus on the evolution of a proposer’s offer
Diversity of Proposers.
We first explore the evolution of
Evolution of proposals in the treatment and control groups. (A–D) The proposers’ offers
The mean value and SD of strategies in experiments
On the other hand, the SD of
Emergence of Proposer Communities.
To discover how network structure affects proposer diversity, we study the spatiotemporal patterns of the proposers. Surprisingly, Fig. 2 shows that in T1 and T2 proposers form local communities, which are shown in different colors (values of
Spatiotemporal patterns of proposers. (A and B) Spatiotemporal patterns of the proposers’ offers
Local communities of proposers. (A and B) A snapshot of the proposers’ offers
Note that although the formation of stable local communities has been predicted by a number of evolutionary game models, it has seldom been observed in experiments using both the UG and other social dilemma games, such as the PD and the PGG. Our work provides experimental evidence that local agreements in the form of communities are spontaneously achieved, which indicates that network structure plays a significant role in evolutionary games. It is worth noting that because the behavior of neighbors (i.e., values of
Behaviors of Proposers and Responders.
To discover how diverse communities emerge, we explore the spatiotemporal diagram of responder behavior. Unlike the behavior of proposers, there is no obvious difference in the behavior of responders between the treatment and the control groups (SI Appendix, Fig. S3). There are no local responder communities, and adjacent responders exhibit inhomogeneity that increases the SD of
Knowing how subjects make decisions is the key to understanding how proposer communities emerge. Proposer communities emerge from local interactions between the inherent diverse behaviors of responders (SI Appendix, Table S1) and the best-response behaviors of proposers. Within communities, proposers share a large fraction of neighbor responders. Because proposer behavior obeys the best-response strategy, they use their knowledge of the previous behavior of their common responders and offer similar amounts of money. These best-response behaviors induce the emergence of a local community. On the other hand, the inherent diverse behaviors of responders result in different communities with different internal agreements. In particular, when responders insist on high acceptance levels, they force their proposer neighbors to increase their offers, which leads to stable communities (Fig. 3C). Thus, local interactions are essential in the formation of local communities. This interpretation is supported by the absence of local communities in control groups with random interactions.
To examine whether some differences between the responders in the treatment group and those in the control groups may be responsible for the communities, we apply a shuffle technique in all of the experiments to test the effect of responder differences (28, 30). Specifically, we exchange the behavior sequences of the responders in the treatment groups with the behavior sequences of their counterparts in the control groups. This reshuffling does not change a player’s dependence on his or her own previous actions because the order of the actions over 60 rounds is not altered. We then calculate the best-response offers in each group and find that the SD of
Simulations on Complex Networks.
Recent interest in evolutionary games in scale-free networks prompts us to explore the UG on scale-free networks (11⇓–13, 15, 18, 20, 30). In general, a scale-free network must be of a certain size to exhibit its typical structural feature, that is, the presence of hubs with a large number of neighbors (48). However, an experimental UG on a large network is limited by our ability to conduct large-scale experiments. To overcome this, we simulate the UG on scale-free networks. Specifically, because proposers use the best-response strategy in treatment and control groups, we assume that proposers in scale-free networks exhibit a similar behavior (31). In contrast, it is difficult to use simple mechanisms to capture the irrational behavior of responders. This problem can be solved by focusing on responder behavior in the experiments and discovering that behaviors are quite similar in the different experiments. We build a database of all responder behavior sequences obtained in the four experiments, randomly pick sequences from the database, and assign them to responders in the scale-free network. Table 2 shows that for different network sizes and average degrees, the SD of
The mean value and SD of proposers’ offers in scale-free networks
To test whether our findings depend on the specific ratio between proposers and responders, we carry out additional simulations for networks with different proposer–responder ratios. Two types of bipartite networks are considered. In the first type all proposers and responders have the same degrees, respectively, and in the second type the degrees of proposers and responders can differ. Similar to the simulations in scale-free networks, we randomly choose responder behaviors from the database that includes all responder behavior sequences and assume that proposers follow the best-response strategy. As shown in SI Appendix, Table S3, for four different proposer–responder ratios, the SD of
Discussion
Our experimental results, shuffle tests, and simulations demonstrate that stable communities with different internal agreements emerge in both regular and complex networks governed by the UG. Thus, the social diversity among proposers emerges and persists. In contrast, in populations with random interactions the proposers remain homogeneous and no communities are established. The diverse communities emerge from the local interactions between irrational responders with inherent heterogeneous demands and rational proposers. In general, proposers with common neighbor responders who act as leaders constitute a community with internal agreement. The different findings between the treatment and control groups indicate that networks are significant in the emergence of social norms, communities, and social diversity. Thus, our work explains how communities with common internal properties and social norms can emerge in a social network in which individuals are diverse. Note that our findings also suggest that even when all proposers have the same intelligent strategy (i.e., best response) and all subjects in the social network have equal status, diverse communities can arise. This result may explain why different social norms can be established even in homogeneous environments (4, 49, 50).
Our results also indicate that local interactions in network structures are only a necessary and not a sufficient condition for the formation of local communities. The self-organization of communities also requires an inherent diversity among individuals. In our UG experiments, local agreements are achieved because a majority of proposers are rational. Some of the irrational responders who insist on high acceptance levels become “leaders” who are followed by their neighboring proposers. This leader effect has been observed in other evolutionary games. For example, previous studies report that cooperating leaders play an important role in increasing a group’s average contribution in PGGs (51, 52). However, how the cooperative communities are established in social dilemma games in social networks remains an open question.
Our work also raises other questions about the emergence of communities and their effects on evolutionary dynamics. First, how does inherent diversity among individuals arise? One possible answer is provided in a recently proposed model by Bear and Rand (53) in which intuitive rejection and deliberative acceptance have evolutionary advantages (53). Thus, heterogeneity at an individual level in our experiments might stem from different deliberation costs in which responders with a higher deliberation cost tend to make decisions based on intuition. Thus, they may have higher acceptance level
Materials and Methods
This research was approved by School of Systems Science, Beijing Normal University on the use of human subjects, and informed consent was obtained from subjects before participation. We recruit 50 participants in each of four groups. Half of them are randomly assigned proposers and half are randomly assigned responders, and assigned player roles do not change during the experiment. Each participant in the treatment groups is assigned a location within a static network and designated either a proposer or a responder. In the treatment groups the UG is structured and participants must play the UG with their immediate neighbors (two subjects are neighbors if they are directly connected). All of the proposers’ neighbors are responders and vice versa. To be consistent with theoretical models, in each round all subjects must use one decision behavior as they interact with their neighbors; that is, a proposer must make the same offer
We compare the results from the treatment groups with the results from the two control groups (populations with random interactions), C1 and C2, to explore the network effect on fairness and altruism. Specifically, to make an unbiased comparison between the treatment and control groups, in C1 and C2 we use a randomly rewired bipartite network with the same node degrees as in the treatment groups. In the rewired network the neighbors of each node are chosen randomly from the other type of nodes in each round, but the number of each node’s neighbors is unchanged.
Each group of experiments includes 60–70 rounds. To prevent any final-round effect, we do not tell the participants the number of rounds they will play. In each round, information gathered in the previous round is given to each player, including the player’s own behavior and payoff and the behavior of the player’s neighbors. The payoff of a player in each round is the sum of the benefits gained from interacting with all of the neighbors of the player normalized by the number of neighbors. To simplify their decision-making processes, we rank neighbor behaviors in a descending order such that players can easily evaluate their behaviors (SI Appendix, Fig. S2). For a further explanation of the experimental design, see SI Appendix, Supplementary Notes 3–5.
Acknowledgments
We thank Zengru Di, A. Sánchez, T. Sasaki, J. Honda, A. Traulsen, and F. Fu for valuable discussion and suggestions. This work was supported by the National Nature Science Foundation of China under Grants 61573064, 71631002, 71401037, and 11301032; the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities and Beijing Nova Programme; and the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada (Individual Discovery Grant). The Boston University work was supported by NSF Grants PHY-1505000, CMMI-1125290, and CHE-1213217, and by Defense Threat Reduction Agency Grant HDTRA1-14-1-0017, and Department of Energy Contract DE-AC07-05Id14517.
Footnotes
- ↵1To whom correspondence may be addressed. Email: zhangby{at}bnu.edu.cn, wenxuwang{at}bnu.edu.cn, or hes{at}bu.edu.
Author contributions: S.C., B.Z., W.-X.W., R.C., and H.E.S. designed research; X.H., S.C., Z.S., B.Z., W.-X.W., and H.E.S. performed research; S.C. and R.C. contributed new reagents/analytic tools; X.H., Z.S., B.Z., W.-X.W., and H.E.S. analyzed data; and X.H., B.Z., W.-X.W., R.C., and H.E.S. wrote the paper.
Reviewers: A.A., Universitat Rovira i Virgili; and D.G.R., Yale University.
The authors declare no conflict of interest.
This article contains supporting information online at www.pnas.org/lookup/suppl/doi:10.1073/pnas.1608164114/-/DCSupplemental.
Freely available online through the PNAS open access option.
References
- ↵.
- Jackson MO
- ↵.
- Barabási A-L
- ↵.
- Dourisboure Y,
- Geraci F,
- Pellegrini M
- ↵.
- Ostrom E
- ↵.
- Rives AW,
- Galitski T
- ↵.
- Axelrod RM
- ↵.
- Von Neumann J,
- Morgenstern O
- ↵.
- Sigmund K
- ↵.
- Skyrms B
- ↵
- ↵.
- Santos FC,
- Pacheco JM,
- Lenaerts T
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵.
- Perc M,
- Gómez-Gardeñes J,
- Szolnoki A,
- Floría LM,
- Moreno Y
- ↵.
- Matamalas JT,
- Poncela-Casasnovas J,
- Gómez S,
- Arenas A
- ↵.
- Sinatra R, et al.
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵.
- Rand DG,
- Arbesman S,
- Christakis NA
- ↵.
- Wang J,
- Suri S,
- Watts DJ
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵.
- Traulsen A,
- Semmann D,
- Sommerfeld RD,
- Krambeck H-J,
- Milinski M
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵.
- Gracia-Lázaro C, et al.
- ↵
- ↵.
- Rand DG,
- Nowak MA,
- Fowler JH,
- Christakis NA
- ↵.
- Wu J-J, et al.
- ↵.
- Oosterbeek H,
- Sloof R,
- van de Kuilen G
- ↵.
- Henrich J, et al.
- ↵.
- Henrich J, et al.
- ↵
- ↵.
- Rand DG,
- Tarnita CE,
- Ohtsuki H,
- Nowak MA
- ↵.
- Cooper DJ,
- Dutcher EG
- ↵.
- Fehr E,
- Schmidt KM
- ↵
- ↵.
- Sanfey AG,
- Rilling JK,
- Aronson JA,
- Nystrom LE,
- Cohen JD
- ↵.
- Brenner T,
- Vriend NJ
- ↵
- ↵.
- Wallace B,
- Cesarini D,
- Lichtenstein P,
- Johannesson M
- ↵.
- Yamagishi T, et al.
- ↵
- ↵.
- Barabási A-L,
- Albert R
- ↵.
- Young HP
- ↵.
- Peysakhovich A,
- Rand DG
- ↵
- ↵
- ↵.
- Bear A,
- Rand DG
Citation Manager Formats
Sign up for Article Alerts
Article Classifications
- Social Sciences
- Social Sciences
- Physical Sciences
- Applied Physical Sciences