Skip to main content

Main menu

  • Home
  • Articles
    • Current
    • Special Feature Articles - Most Recent
    • Special Features
    • Colloquia
    • Collected Articles
    • PNAS Classics
    • List of Issues
  • Front Matter
    • Front Matter Portal
    • Journal Club
  • News
    • For the Press
    • This Week In PNAS
    • PNAS in the News
  • Podcasts
  • Authors
    • Information for Authors
    • Editorial and Journal Policies
    • Submission Procedures
    • Fees and Licenses
  • Submit
  • Submit
  • About
    • Editorial Board
    • PNAS Staff
    • FAQ
    • Accessibility Statement
    • Rights and Permissions
    • Site Map
  • Contact
  • Journal Club
  • Subscribe
    • Subscription Rates
    • Subscriptions FAQ
    • Open Access
    • Recommend PNAS to Your Librarian

User menu

  • Log in
  • My Cart

Search

  • Advanced search
Home
Home
  • Log in
  • My Cart

Advanced Search

  • Home
  • Articles
    • Current
    • Special Feature Articles - Most Recent
    • Special Features
    • Colloquia
    • Collected Articles
    • PNAS Classics
    • List of Issues
  • Front Matter
    • Front Matter Portal
    • Journal Club
  • News
    • For the Press
    • This Week In PNAS
    • PNAS in the News
  • Podcasts
  • Authors
    • Information for Authors
    • Editorial and Journal Policies
    • Submission Procedures
    • Fees and Licenses
  • Submit
Research Article

Americans overestimate the intergenerational persistence in income ranks

View ORCID ProfileSiwei Cheng and Fangqi Wen
  1. aDepartment of Sociology, New York University, New York, NY 10012

See allHide authors and affiliations

PNAS July 9, 2019 116 (28) 13909-13914; first published June 24, 2019; https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1814688116
Siwei Cheng
aDepartment of Sociology, New York University, New York, NY 10012
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  • ORCID record for Siwei Cheng
  • For correspondence: siwei.cheng@nyu.edu
Fangqi Wen
aDepartment of Sociology, New York University, New York, NY 10012
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  1. Edited by David B. Grusky, Stanford University, Stanford, CA, and accepted by Editorial Board Member Mary C. Waters May 23, 2019 (received for review August 26, 2018)

  • Article
  • Figures & SI
  • Info & Metrics
  • PDF
Loading

Significance

Intergenerational mobility indicates the openness within a society. The question of how Americans think about socioeconomic mobility prospects is drawing growing attention from scholars and policy makers. Our study proposes a survey instrument that connects the empirical literature on patterns of mobility with the literature on the public perceptions of mobility. With large-scale, population-representative data, we show that Americans overestimate the intergenerational persistence in income ranks. That is, they tend to see greater inequality of economic prospects between children from rich and poor families. These results highlight the need for policy and political solutions that seriously engage with Americans’ concerns about the equality of opportunity in the society.

Abstract

Recent research suggests that intergenerational income mobility has remained low and stable in America, but popular discourse routinely assumes that Americans are optimistic about mobility prospects in society. Examining these 2 seemingly contradictory observations requires a careful measurement of the public’s perceptions of mobility. Unlike most previous work that measures perceptions about mobility outcomes for the overall population or certain subgroups, we propose a survey instrument that emphasizes the variation in perceived mobility prospects for hypothetical children across parent income ranks. Based on this survey instrument, we derive the perceived relationship between the income ranks of parents and children, which can then be compared against the actual rank–rank relationship reported by empirical work based on tax data. We fielded this instrument in a general population survey experiment (n = 3,077). Our results suggest that Americans overestimate the intergenerational persistence in income ranks. They overestimate economic prospects for children from rich families and underestimate economic prospects for those from poor families.

  • intergenerational mobility
  • equality of opportunity
  • public perception
  • mobility optimism
  • rank–rank relationship

Two contradictory observations can be made about economic mobility in America. On one hand, a sizable body of literature suggests that intergenerational mobility—that is, the odds that children will move up or down relative to the socioeconomic status of their parents—has remained low and remarkably stable in the United States from the 1950s cohort to the early 1990s cohort (1⇓–3). America also ranks low in intergenerational mobility compared with other countries (4, 5). On the other hand, Americans seem quite optimistic about mobility, believing that the opportunities for individuals to move up the social ladder are widespread and relatively independent of their family background. Such optimism is emphasized in empirical work (6, 7); shared among the general public (6, 8⇓⇓⇓–12); and tied to Americans’ beliefs in individualism, social liberalism, and egalitarianism (11, 13, 14). Americans also tend to think that their country has higher mobility than Europe, although the empirical data reveal the opposite (5, 9).

The apparent contradiction between intergenerational mobility in reality and its public perceptions creates an intriguing puzzle: how shall we reconcile (i) Americans’ optimism about mobility and (ii) their day-to-day experience of remarkably unequal distribution of opportunities? There are several tentative answers. First, lay people may be simply oblivious to the social reality. Second, the public’s perceptions track the social changes with a time lag and are out of date. Third, as recent work suggests, the finding of mobility optimism may not always hold up (15⇓⇓⇓–19).

While these answers all seem plausible, they all tend to simplify mobility as an undifferentiated measure. We approach this puzzle with a different route. We argue that people may think about mobility prospects differentially across the parent income distribution. Hence, when measuring their perceptions, it is important to consider the variation in perceived mobility outcomes for hypothetical children from different parent income ranks. This enables us to measure the equality of opportunity across parental socioeconomic background, a central focus of empirical research on intergenerational mobility (1⇓–3).

Motivated by the above argument and building on the empirical estimates of the relationship between the parent and child income ranks reported by an emerging line of work using administrative tax data (1), we propose a survey instrument to differentiate among perceptions about mobility outcomes for hypothetical children from different parent income ranks. Specifically, this survey instrument asks the respondents to predict the adult income ranks of children whose parent income ranks at different percentiles of the distribution. Data collected from this survey instrument allow us to estimate the perceived rank–rank relationship “in people’s minds.” Then, by contrasting the perceived rank–rank relationship with its empirical estimates, we present an analytic framework for assessing the public’s (mis-)perceptions about the inequality in mobility chances between children from rich and poor families.

We fielded this instrument on a nationally representative sample of 3,077 adults in the United States. Our data suggest that Americans hold pessimistic perceptions about the equality of economic outcomes between children from rich and poor families. They overestimate the economic prospect for children from rich families and underestimate the economic prospect for those from poor families. This results in an overestimation of the intergenerational persistence in income ranks.

Prior Research on Perceptions of Economic Mobility

Intergenerational mobility indicates the openness, fluidity, and fairness in a society. Promoting the equality of opportunity has become a pressing policy concern, particularly in the recent era of rising inequality. The empirical literature on economic mobility is accompanied by a related literature on perceptions about mobility. The public perceptions about mobility are construed as an ideological condition under which attitudes of and preference toward inequality and redistributive policies are formed. How people view the status of mobility affects their openness or resistance to policy solutions that potentially reduce inequality and promote mobility (9, 10, 13, 20⇓⇓–23).

One strand of research suggests that the general public holds optimistic views on economic mobility in America (9, 11, 12). For example, Americans overestimate the probability that children starting from the bottom can make it to the top of the income distribution and underestimate the probability of a bottom-quintile child remaining at the bottom in America, while their Europeans counterparts hold more pessimistic perceptions about mobility in their countries (9). Another line of work, however, suggests that Americans are actually concerned about economic mobility (15⇓⇓–18) and that Americans have more enduring structural perceptions about mobility than widely assumed (18, 19). Furthermore, Americans’ concerns about the lack of opportunity have played a role in shaping their concerns about economic inequality (13, 24). Growth in economic inequality increases skepticism regarding the opportunity structure in society that, in turn, may motivate support for equity-enhancing policies (18). A detailed literature summary is presented in SI Appendix, section 1.

While previous work has taken important steps to understand the public perceptions of mobility, most of those measures tend to focus on the perceived transition probabilities for children from specific subgroups, such as the likelihood to move from bottom to top or from top to bottom (9, 12). However, these findings are sensitive to whether the socioeconomic spectrum is divided into 5 (25) or 3 (15) strata, whether phrases like “stayed in the bottom” or “moved up” were used (26), and the empirical benchmark against which people’s perceptions are compared (17). Another drawback is that these measures typically involve the calculation of probability, which is prone to cognitive errors by lay people, especially compared with average or expectation-based measures (16, 27, 28). Most importantly, these previous measures tend to focus on mobility chances for 1 or a few specific income groups, such as the top or bottom quintile. They have not examined the differences in perceived mobility prospects across the full spectrum of parent income ranks.

A Rank–Rank-Based Survey Instrument

This study contributes to current scholarship by proposing a survey instrument for measuring the variation in mobility perceptions, which is based on the relationship between parent and child income ranks. We present each respondent with 3 questions of the same format. The question first describes a hypothetical person whose parents’ income ranks at the pth percentile of the income distribution. A picture is also presented to illustrate the income ranking (SI Appendix, section 2). We then ask the respondent to drag a slider on a marked bar to indicate where she thinks this child’s own family income will rank at age 40. Each respondent will answer 3 such questions in which the hypothetical person’s parent income ranks (i.e., p) are drawn randomly without replacement from a total of 9 deciles (i.e., p=10,20,…,80,90). SI Appendix, section 2 presents the details about the survey instrument.

This survey instrument has several advantages. First, the question presents a reasonably tractable task to the respondents, as it avoids asking lay people to evaluate complicated transition probabilities. Second, as each respondent is asked to consider mobility outcomes for only 3 hypothetical individuals, each from a different parent income rank, the survey imposes a relatively light cognitive burden. These 2 advantages were confirmed in our pilot study, where we recruited 50 respondents via Amazon Mechanical Turk and asked them to describe their logic of reasoning in answering these questions (SI Appendix, section 3 has details and additional checks).

Most importantly, data collected from this instrument can be used to estimate the perceived rank–rank relationship, which can then be compared against the actual rank–rank relationship to describe the direction and degree of mobility misperception. To do this, for a sample of size n, we pool the answers across individuals to form a total of 3n (3 deciles per person × n persons) data points. Then, we plot the perceived and actual rank–rank lines against each other on the same plot for comparison. For both lines, a steeper rank–rank slope indicates greater intergenerational persistence in income ranks (i.e., lower mobility).

Fig. 1 illustrates 4 example cases for this comparison. In Fig. 1, solid (dashed) lines represent the actual (perceived) rank–rank relationship. The area Sover denotes the amount of overestimated mobility prospect, and Sunder denotes underestimated mobility prospect. A steeper perceived slope (βP) relative to the slope in reality (βR) indicates pessimism about the equality of mobility prospects between children in rich and poor families and vice versa.

Fig. 1.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 1.

Illustration of rank–rank lines in perception (dashed) and in reality (solid).

Case A presents an example in which the perceived rank–rank line is parallel to the actual line (βP=βR) but is placed at a higher vertical position at every level of parent income (Sover>0 and Sunder=0). This indicates that the public overestimates economic outcomes for children from all family backgrounds and that there are no misperceptions about the disparities in mobility outcomes. Case B presents an example in which the slope in the perceived line is steeper than the slope in reality (βP>βR), indicating pessimism about the equality of opportunity. In this case, people overestimate economic prospects for children from the upper one-half of the parent income distribution to the same extent as they underestimate economic outcomes for children from the lower one-half of the parent income distribution (Sover=Sunder). Hence, across the entire parent income distribution, the positive and negative misperceptions of economic prospects cancel each other out and generate a 0 average (Sover−Sunder=0).

The next 2 cases illustrate scenarios in which the public has misperceptions about the equality of opportunity (βP≠βR) and meanwhile, over- or underestimates economic prospects on average (i.e., Sover≠Sunder). Case C illustrates a scenario of pessimism about equality of opportunity (βP>βR). Meanwhile, the public overestimates economic outcomes for those at the middle- and higher-income ranks to a greater extent than they underestimate the economic outcomes for those at lower-income ranks (Sover>Sunder), leading to an overestimation about children’s economic prospects on average. By the same logic, Case D illustrates an overestimation of the equality of opportunity (βP<βR) but an underestimation of average economic outcomes (Sover<Sunder).

Two important features of this survey instrument are worth noting. First, in principle, Sover and Sunder should be equal, because on average, the amount of increase in income rank should be offset by the same amount of decrease. However, in the survey instrument, we do not give zero-sum instructions, because that would impose too much cognitive burden. Hence, it is possible that the respondents will overestimate (Cases A and C) or underestimate (Case B) the population-average income ranks, resulting in biases toward upward or downward mobility. An important advantage of our proposed measure is that the comparison between βP and βR is not prone to such bias, because the perceived rank–rank slope depends on the inequality in perceived mobility prospects rather than the average level. Second, because the parent income rank needs to be given in the question, there may be an anchoring problem: respondents’ answers may gravitate toward the parent income rank shown to them in the survey question, resulting in a bias toward the diagonal line in the perceived rank–rank line. In a robustness check, we removed the data points around the diagonal line. Results suggest that the anchoring effect is unlikely to affect our main conclusions (SI Appendix, section 6). We recommend that this robustness check be included in future applications of this survey instrument.

The key takeaway from the 4 example cases illustrated in Fig. 1 is that the problem of measuring the public’s (mis-)perceptions of mobility prospects across the parent income distribution can be reduced to a simpler problem of obtaining 4 parameters: Sover, Sunder, βP, and βR. Here, the first 3 can be estimated from the rank–rank-based survey instrument that we propose; the last parameter, βR, is obtained from estimates reported in large-sample empirical studies.

Data Collection

We collected data from a probability-based representative sample of 3,077 adults in the United States. Participants were recruited during February 2018 via National Opinion Research Center’s AmeriSpeak panel maintained by the Time-Sharing Experiments in the Social Sciences. We randomly assigned the respondents to 3 groups that vary in the attributes of the hypothetical person: (i) a baseline group in which there is no specific description (n = 1,858), (ii) a “college graduate” treatment group in which we describe the person as having a college degree (n = 606), and (iii) a “hard-working” treatment group in which we describe the person as working very hard in life (n = 613). These descriptions were added right after the information on the person’s parent income rank is given. Our analyses are weighted by AmeriSpeak panel weights. Weighted and unweighted sample statistics are presented in SI Appendix, section 4.

For the benchmark of actual mobility, we rely on the rank–rank relationship reported by recent work using tax records (1). These estimates do not suffer from measurement errors that are prevalent in survey data (29). Moreover, unlike other mobility measures, such as the intergenerational elasticity, which tend to be nonlinear, the rank–rank relationship in the United States can be well approximated by a linear line, the slope of which provides a succinct way for quantifying income mobility.

Empirical Results

Baseline Group.

As no additional information of the hypothetical person is given, results from the baseline group reflect the perceptions of overall mobility. Fig. 2 presents the conditional densities of child’s perceived income rank by parent income rank. The 3 horizontal lines at each parent income rank represent the 75th, 50th, and 25th percentiles of the child’s perceived income rank. While the child’s perceived income rank varies at each parent income rank, the median and the upper and lower quartiles of the perceived income rank distribution all increase steadily with parent income rank, showing intergenerational persistence in income ranks.

Fig. 2.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 2.

Conditional density distributions of child’s perceived income rank.

How well does the perceived rank–rank relationship match the reality? Fig. 3 contrasts the perceived rank–rank relationship in our data and the actual rank–rank line. For illustration, we have also plotted 2 auxiliary lines (Fig. 3, light blue dashed lines) indicating perfect income persistence (Fig. 3, diagonal 45° line) and perfect income mobility (Fig. 3, horizontal line where child’s mean rank = 50). A steeper rank–rank slope indicates greater closeness to perfect persistence, and a flatter slope indicates greater closeness to perfect mobility.

Fig. 3.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 3.

Rank–rank relationship in perception and in reality.

The pattern shown in Fig. 3 is akin to Case C in Fig. 1. The 2 lines cross at around the 34th percentile of parent income rank. To the right of this crossing point—that is, for children from families in the middle or upper parts of the income distribution—the public overestimates children’s income ranks. To the left of this crossing point, perceived economic ranks are lower than reality, indicating an underestimation of the economic prospects for children from the lower end of the income spectrum. Observe that Sover>Sunder, which implies that the public overestimates children’s economic prospects across their parent income ranks. Meanwhile, the slope of the perceived rank–rank line is steeper than the actual rank–rank line (0.65 vs. 0.34), indicating that the public perceives greater inequality in income ranks between children from rich and poor families than there actually is in reality.

Table 1 quantifies these results. Sover−Sunder captures the net difference between the child’s perceived and actual income ranks across the parent income distribution. The degree of pessimism about the equality of mobility prospects can be calculated as the difference between perceived and actual rank–rank slopes, which equals 0.31 (=0.65 − 0.34). That is, for a 1-unit increase in the parent income rank, the child’s expected income rank rises by 0.34 units in reality, but an average American expects it to rise by 0.65 units. That is, Americans overestimate the intergenerational persistence in income ranks. SI Appendix, section 6 presents additional results on perceived immobility, upward mobility, and downward mobility by parent income.

View this table:
  • View inline
  • View popup
Table 1.

Estimated model parameters and derived quantities

Between-Group Variations.

We next examine whether the public’s perceptions of mobility vary by respondents’ characteristics. To examine the between-group variations, we estimate a multilevel model predicting the child’s perceived income rank for respondent i and item k (=1, 2, and 3). Level 1 model isYikchild=β0iP+β1iP⋅Yikparent+ϵik,[1]

The random intercept (β0iP) and slope (β1iP) then depend on the respondent’s attributes X in the level 2 model:β0iP=Xγ0+ν0iβ1iP=Xγ1+ν1i.[2]

We present the coefficients predicting the slope in Fig. 4 and the full coefficient estimates in SI Appendix, section 7. Here, the effects of covariates on slope are of particular interest. A positive (negative) coefficient indicates greater (lesser) perceived inequality in mobility chances compared with the reference group. Respondents who are age 18–29, are white, are living in a household with $30,000–$99,999 annual income, own a house or pay some rent, lean liberal, or have a bachelor’s degree are more pessimistic about the equality of mobility prospects across parent income ranks.

Fig. 4.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 4.

Effects of respondent’s characteristics on perceived rank–rank slope (point estimates with 90% CIs). BA, bachelor’s degree; HS, high school.

Fig. 5 demonstrates the perceived rank–rank relationship by respondents’ education, household income, and political ideology. Higher education and income are associated with greater pessimism about mobility, a finding also noted by previous studies (9, 12, 25). Among those without a high school degree, the perceived rank–rank line is only slightly steeper than the reality; respondents with a bachelor’s degree are most pessimistic about the equality of mobility outcomes, particularly for children from the lowest 30% of income distribution. Respondents in all income groups are pessimistic about the equality of mobility prospects, and the perceived rank–rank slope is flattest among those with less than $30,000 annual household income.

Fig. 5.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 5.

Perceived rank–rank relationship by respondent’s education, household income, and political ideology.

Liberals are more pessimistic about the equality of mobility prospects, a finding consistent with prior findings (9, 15, 25). As discussed earlier, our rank–rank measure has the strength of allowing us to differentiate between perceptions of mobility prospects across parent income ranks. For example, here, the results suggest that respondents with different political orientation do not differ much in the perceived mobility for children with high parent income, but their perceptions differ substantially for children from the lower part of the income distribution.

Our analysis and interpretation above have focused on whether between-group differences exist rather than why they exist. The complex mechanisms behind these between-group differences are beyond the scope of this paper, and future research is needed to better understand the patterns of these differences. However, these results also suggest that Americans’ pessimism about the equality of mobility prospects across parent income ranks is quite robust across subgroups of the population.

College Graduate Treatment and Hard-Working Treatment.

Comparing the perceived rank–rank lines in the 2 treatment groups with the baseline group will tell us the extent to which the public perceives a college degree or hard work as a factor for promoting intergenerational mobility. Fig. 6 demonstrates the results. The college degree treatment raises the intercept (P = 0.000) and flattens the slope (P = 0.057) for the rank–rank line. When the hypothetical person has a college degree, respondents now perceive slightly higher-income ranks for children across the parent income spectrum, especially for those in the middle and lower parts. Consistent with the findings from empirical work (30, 31), the perceived rank–rank slope decreases when the hypothetical person has a college degree, but the perceived slope change (0.65–0.56) is much smaller than the change in reality (0.34–0.15) reported by recent empirical work (30). Hence, the public underestimates not only the amount of mobility but also, the contribution of a college degree to mobility. The perceived rank–rank line for the hard-working treatment has a slightly higher intercept (P = 0.086) than the baseline, and there is very small difference in their slopes (P = 0.955).

Fig. 6.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 6.

Perceived rank–rank relationship in baseline and treatment groups.

Some nonlinearity of the rank–rank lines can be observed here: the 3 rank–rank lines are very close to each other at the upper 40% of the distribution but diverge for the lower 60%. Hence, we estimated the perceived slopes restricting to the lower 60% of parent income ranks. The changes in slopes are slightly higher but still very small. The pattern holds when we break down the sample by education and income (SI Appendix, section 8). These results suggest that the public remains pessimistic about the equality of opportunity even when the hypothetical person is assigned attributes that should promote economic mobility. The small treatment effects could also be due to the weakness of the intervention. The explanations behind the public’s pessimism about the role of college in promoting education warrant future research.

Robustness Checks.

Our results are robust to several alternative specifications, including using the median instead of mean of child’s income rank (SI Appendix, section 9), using a nonlinear smooth function to model the rank–rank curve (SI Appendix, section 10), and separating the data by the order in which the items appeared in the survey (SI Appendix, section 11). To test whether the findings are driven by potential misperceptions about income inequality, we provided a subgroup (n = 586) with some factual information on the household income distribution before they answered the original survey questions; this did not change the findings (SI Appendix, section 12 has a detailed discussion).

Discussion and Conclusion

The question of how Americans think about intergenerational mobility draws growing attention from scholars and policy makers who seek to understand its consequences for public opinion, political action, and policy support. In examining mobility perceptions, previous work has mainly focused on the perceived transition probabilities for children from specific positions in the parent income distribution. This study proposes a rank–rank-based survey instrument for measuring public perceptions of the inequality in mobility prospects. The key strengths of this measure are 3-fold. First, this measure differentiates perceived economic outcomes for children across parent income ranks, which enables us to measure the perceptions about the inequality in mobility prospects. Second, the survey item presents the respondents with a relatively simple, tractable task and requires little cognitive burden. Third, the perceived rank–rank line derived from the data can be directly compared with an up-to-date empirical benchmark based on administrative tax data.

In accounting for the differential perceptions of economic outcomes for hypothetical children from different parent income ranks, we have now come to form a more comprehensive picture of mobility perceptions. We conclude that Americans are pessimistic about the equality of economic prospects among children born to rich and poor parents. This finding challenges the prior belief that Americans hold an optimistic view about the openness of the society and is instead consistent with the idea that the everyday experiences of highly unequal opportunity between children from poorer and wealthier families may have shaped how the general public thinks about the opportunity structure of the American society. The results also indicate that the pessimism about the equality of mobility prospects results from their overestimation of income ranks for children from families in the middle and higher ends of the income distribution and their underestimation of income ranks for children from low-income families.

Reading our findings along with recent work on the public beliefs about inequality and mobility (13, 18), we suggest that the once-prevailing belief (that Americans tolerate inequality, because they see great promise in economic mobility) may be misleading. With large-scale, population-representative data, we show that Americans are aware of, and in fact quite pessimistic about, the remarkably unequal distribution of economic outcomes by family background. These findings call for an extended scope of inquiries that bridge the empirical research on economic mobility with research on the social, political, and psychological processes that shape how the public thinks about it. We also highlight the need for policy and political solutions to seriously engage with Americans’ concerns about the equality of opportunity in the society.

Methods

This research was reviewed and approved by the Institutional Review Board at New York University. Informed consent was obtained from all participants.

Acknowledgments

This study received support from the Seed Award from the Institute of Human Development and Social Change at New York University, and the Time-Sharing Experiments for the Social Sciences through NSF Grant 0818839.

Footnotes

  • ↵1To whom correspondence may be addressed. Email: siwei.cheng{at}nyu.edu.
  • Author contributions: S.C. designed research; S.C. and F.W. performed research; S.C. and F.W. analyzed data; and S.C. and F.W. wrote the paper.

  • The authors declare no conflict of interest.

  • This article is a PNAS Direct Submission. D.B.G. is a guest editor invited by the Editorial Board.

  • This article contains supporting information online at www.pnas.org/lookup/suppl/doi:10.1073/pnas.1814688116/-/DCSupplemental.

Published under the PNAS license.

References

  1. ↵
    1. R. Chetty,
    2. N. Hendren,
    3. P. Kline,
    4. E. Saez
    , Where is the land of opportunity? The geography of intergenerational mobility in the United States. Q. J. Econ. 129, 1553–1623 (2014).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  2. ↵
    1. M. Hout
    , Americans’ occupational status reflects the status of both of their parents. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 115, 9527–9532 (2018).
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  3. ↵
    1. C.-I. Lee,
    2. G. Solon
    , Trends in intergenerational income mobility. Rev. Econ. Stat. 91, 766–772 (2009).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  4. ↵
    1. A. Björklund,
    2. M. Jäntti
    , Intergenerational income mobility in Sweden compared to the United States. Am. Econ. Rev. 87, 1009–1018 (1997).
    OpenUrl
  5. ↵
    1. M. Jantti et al.
    , “American exceptionalism in a new light: A comparison of intergenerational earnings mobility in the nordic countries, the United Kingdom and the United States” (Discussion paper 1938, IZA, 2006, http://ftp.iza.org/dp1938.pdf).
  6. ↵
    1. G. Esping-Andersen
    , The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (John Wiley & Sons, 2013).
  7. ↵
    1. S. M. Lipset,
    2. R. Bendix
    , Social Mobility in Industrial Society (Transaction Publishers, 1959).
  8. ↵
    1. J. T. Adams
    , The Epic of America (Transaction Publishers, 1931).
  9. ↵
    1. A. Alesina,
    2. S. Stantcheva,
    3. E. Teso
    , Intergenerational mobility and preferences for redistribution. Am. Econ. Rev. 108, 521–554 (2018).
    OpenUrl
  10. ↵
    1. J. Huber,
    2. W. Form
    , Income and Ideology (Free Press, New York, 1973).
  11. ↵
    1. J. R. Kluegel,
    2. E. R. Smith
    , Beliefs About Inequality: Americans’ Views of What Is and What Ought to Be (Transaction Publishers, 1986).
  12. ↵
    1. M. W. Kraus,
    2. J. J. X. Tan
    , Americans overestimate social class mobility. J. Exp. Soc. Psychol. 58, 101–111 (2015).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  13. ↵
    1. L. McCall
    , The Undeserving Rich: American Beliefs About Inequality, Opportunity, and Redistribution (Cambridge Univ Press, 2013).
  14. ↵
    1. H. McClosky,
    2. J. Zaller
    , The American Ethos: Public Attitudes Toward Capitalism and Democracy (Harvard Univ Press, 1984).
  15. ↵
    1. J. R. Chambers,
    2. L. K. Swan,
    3. M. Heesacker
    , Perceptions of us social mobility are divided (and distorted) along ideological lines. Psychol. Sci. 26, 413–423(2015).
    OpenUrlCrossRefPubMed
  16. ↵
    1. L. K. Swan,
    2. J. R. Chambers,
    3. M. Heesacker,
    4. S. S. Nero
    , How should we measure Americans’ perceptions of socio-economic mobility?Judgment Decis. Making 12, 507–515 (2017).
    OpenUrl
  17. ↵
    1. S. S. Nero,
    2. L. K. Swan,
    3. J. R. Chambers,
    4. M. Heesacker
    , Still no compelling evidence that Americans overestimate upward socio-economic mobility rates: Reply to Davidai & Gilovich (2018). Judgment Decis. Making 13, 305–308 (2018).
    OpenUrl
  18. ↵
    1. L. McCall,
    2. D. Burk,
    3. M. Laperrière,
    4. J. A. Richeson
    , Exposure to rising inequality shapes Americans’ opportunity beliefs and policy support. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 114, 9593–9598 (2017).
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  19. ↵
    1. I. Kirsch,
    2. H. Braun
    1. L. McCall
    , “Political and policy responses to problems of inequality and opportunity: Past, present, and future” in The Dynamics of Opportunity in America, I. Kirsch, H. Braun, Eds. (Springer, Cham, Switzerland, 2016), pp. 415–442.
  20. ↵
    1. A. Alesina,
    2. E. La Ferrara
    . Preferences for redistribution in the land of opportunities. J. Public Econ. 89, 897–931 (2005).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  21. ↵
    1. M. V. Day,
    2. S. T. Fiske
    , Movin’on up? How perceptions of social mobility affect our willingness to defend the system. Soc. Psychol. Pers. Sci. 8, 267–274 (2017).
    OpenUrl
  22. ↵
    1. K. S. Newman
    , Falling from Grace: The Experience of Downward Mobility in the American Middle Class (Free Press, New York, 1988).
  23. ↵
    1. L. Osberg,
    2. T. Smeeding
    , “Fair” inequality? Attitudes toward pay differentials: The United States in comparative perspective. Am. Sociol. Rev. 71, 450–473 (2006).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  24. ↵
    1. L. McCall,
    2. L. Kenworthy
    , Americans’ social policy preferences in the era of rising inequality. Perspect. Polit. 7, 459–484 (2009).
    OpenUrl
  25. ↵
    1. S. Davidai,
    2. T. Gilovich
    , Building a more mobile America - one income quintile at a time. Perspect. Psychol. Sci. 10, 60–71 (2015).
    OpenUrlCrossRefPubMed
  26. ↵
    1. S. Davidai,
    2. T. Gilovich
    , How should we think about Americans’ beliefs about economic mobility?Judgment Decis. Making 13, 297 (2018).
    OpenUrl
  27. ↵
    1. K. Eriksson,
    2. B. Simpson
    , What do Americans know about inequality? It depends on how you ask them. Judgment Decis. Making 7, 741–745 (2012).
    OpenUrl
  28. ↵
    1. D. Kahneman,
    2. A. Tversky
    , Subjective probability: A judgment of representativeness. Cognit. Psychol. 3, 430–454 (1972).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  29. ↵
    1. P. Mitnik,
    2. V. Bryant,
    3. M. Weber,
    4. D. B. Grusky
    , New Estimates of Intergenerational Mobility Using Administrative Data (Statistics of Income Division, Internal Revenue Service, Washington, DC, 2015).
  30. ↵
    1. R. Chetty,
    2. J. N. Friedman,
    3. E. Saez,
    4. N. Turner,
    5. D. Yagan
    , “Mobility report cards: The role of colleges in intergenerational mobility” (Tech. Rep. 23618, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, 2017).
  31. ↵
    1. M. Hout
    , More universalism, less structural mobility: The American occupational structure in the 1980s. Am. J. Sociol. 93, 1358–1400 (1988).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
PreviousNext
Back to top
Article Alerts
Email Article

Thank you for your interest in spreading the word on PNAS.

NOTE: We only request your email address so that the person you are recommending the page to knows that you wanted them to see it, and that it is not junk mail. We do not capture any email address.

Enter multiple addresses on separate lines or separate them with commas.
Americans overestimate the intergenerational persistence in income ranks
(Your Name) has sent you a message from PNAS
(Your Name) thought you would like to see the PNAS web site.
CAPTCHA
This question is for testing whether or not you are a human visitor and to prevent automated spam submissions.
Citation Tools
Americans overestimate the intergenerational persistence in income ranks
Siwei Cheng, Fangqi Wen
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences Jul 2019, 116 (28) 13909-13914; DOI: 10.1073/pnas.1814688116

Citation Manager Formats

  • BibTeX
  • Bookends
  • EasyBib
  • EndNote (tagged)
  • EndNote 8 (xml)
  • Medlars
  • Mendeley
  • Papers
  • RefWorks Tagged
  • Ref Manager
  • RIS
  • Zotero
Request Permissions
Share
Americans overestimate the intergenerational persistence in income ranks
Siwei Cheng, Fangqi Wen
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences Jul 2019, 116 (28) 13909-13914; DOI: 10.1073/pnas.1814688116
del.icio.us logo Digg logo Reddit logo Twitter logo CiteULike logo Facebook logo Google logo Mendeley logo
  • Tweet Widget
  • Facebook Like
  • Mendeley logo Mendeley

Article Classifications

  • Social Sciences
  • Social Sciences
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences: 116 (28)
Table of Contents

Submit

Sign up for Article Alerts

Jump to section

  • Article
    • Abstract
    • Prior Research on Perceptions of Economic Mobility
    • A Rank–Rank-Based Survey Instrument
    • Data Collection
    • Empirical Results
    • Discussion and Conclusion
    • Methods
    • Acknowledgments
    • Footnotes
    • References
  • Figures & SI
  • Info & Metrics
  • PDF

You May Also be Interested in

Water from a faucet fills a glass.
News Feature: How “forever chemicals” might impair the immune system
Researchers are exploring whether these ubiquitous fluorinated molecules might worsen infections or hamper vaccine effectiveness.
Image credit: Shutterstock/Dmitry Naumov.
Reflection of clouds in the still waters of Mono Lake in California.
Inner Workings: Making headway with the mysteries of life’s origins
Recent experiments and simulations are starting to answer some fundamental questions about how life came to be.
Image credit: Shutterstock/Radoslaw Lecyk.
Cave in coastal Kenya with tree growing in the middle.
Journal Club: Small, sharp blades mark shift from Middle to Later Stone Age in coastal Kenya
Archaeologists have long tried to define the transition between the two time periods.
Image credit: Ceri Shipton.
Illustration of groups of people chatting
Exploring the length of human conversations
Adam Mastroianni and Daniel Gilbert explore why conversations almost never end when people want them to.
Listen
Past PodcastsSubscribe
Panda bear hanging in a tree
How horse manure helps giant pandas tolerate cold
A study finds that giant pandas roll in horse manure to increase their cold tolerance.
Image credit: Fuwen Wei.

Similar Articles

Site Logo
Powered by HighWire
  • Submit Manuscript
  • Twitter
  • Facebook
  • RSS Feeds
  • Email Alerts

Articles

  • Current Issue
  • Special Feature Articles – Most Recent
  • List of Issues

PNAS Portals

  • Anthropology
  • Chemistry
  • Classics
  • Front Matter
  • Physics
  • Sustainability Science
  • Teaching Resources

Information

  • Authors
  • Editorial Board
  • Reviewers
  • Subscribers
  • Librarians
  • Press
  • Cozzarelli Prize
  • Site Map
  • PNAS Updates
  • FAQs
  • Accessibility Statement
  • Rights & Permissions
  • About
  • Contact

Feedback    Privacy/Legal

Copyright © 2021 National Academy of Sciences. Online ISSN 1091-6490