Americans overestimate the intergenerational persistence in income ranks
See allHide authors and affiliations
Edited by David B. Grusky, Stanford University, Stanford, CA, and accepted by Editorial Board Member Mary C. Waters May 23, 2019 (received for review August 26, 2018)

Significance
Intergenerational mobility indicates the openness within a society. The question of how Americans think about socioeconomic mobility prospects is drawing growing attention from scholars and policy makers. Our study proposes a survey instrument that connects the empirical literature on patterns of mobility with the literature on the public perceptions of mobility. With large-scale, population-representative data, we show that Americans overestimate the intergenerational persistence in income ranks. That is, they tend to see greater inequality of economic prospects between children from rich and poor families. These results highlight the need for policy and political solutions that seriously engage with Americans’ concerns about the equality of opportunity in the society.
Abstract
Recent research suggests that intergenerational income mobility has remained low and stable in America, but popular discourse routinely assumes that Americans are optimistic about mobility prospects in society. Examining these 2 seemingly contradictory observations requires a careful measurement of the public’s perceptions of mobility. Unlike most previous work that measures perceptions about mobility outcomes for the overall population or certain subgroups, we propose a survey instrument that emphasizes the variation in perceived mobility prospects for hypothetical children across parent income ranks. Based on this survey instrument, we derive the perceived relationship between the income ranks of parents and children, which can then be compared against the actual rank–rank relationship reported by empirical work based on tax data. We fielded this instrument in a general population survey experiment (n = 3,077). Our results suggest that Americans overestimate the intergenerational persistence in income ranks. They overestimate economic prospects for children from rich families and underestimate economic prospects for those from poor families.
- intergenerational mobility
- equality of opportunity
- public perception
- mobility optimism
- rank–rank relationship
Two contradictory observations can be made about economic mobility in America. On one hand, a sizable body of literature suggests that intergenerational mobility—that is, the odds that children will move up or down relative to the socioeconomic status of their parents—has remained low and remarkably stable in the United States from the 1950s cohort to the early 1990s cohort (1⇓–3). America also ranks low in intergenerational mobility compared with other countries (4, 5). On the other hand, Americans seem quite optimistic about mobility, believing that the opportunities for individuals to move up the social ladder are widespread and relatively independent of their family background. Such optimism is emphasized in empirical work (6, 7); shared among the general public (6, 8⇓⇓⇓–12); and tied to Americans’ beliefs in individualism, social liberalism, and egalitarianism (11, 13, 14). Americans also tend to think that their country has higher mobility than Europe, although the empirical data reveal the opposite (5, 9).
The apparent contradiction between intergenerational mobility in reality and its public perceptions creates an intriguing puzzle: how shall we reconcile (i) Americans’ optimism about mobility and (ii) their day-to-day experience of remarkably unequal distribution of opportunities? There are several tentative answers. First, lay people may be simply oblivious to the social reality. Second, the public’s perceptions track the social changes with a time lag and are out of date. Third, as recent work suggests, the finding of mobility optimism may not always hold up (15⇓⇓⇓–19).
While these answers all seem plausible, they all tend to simplify mobility as an undifferentiated measure. We approach this puzzle with a different route. We argue that people may think about mobility prospects differentially across the parent income distribution. Hence, when measuring their perceptions, it is important to consider the variation in perceived mobility outcomes for hypothetical children from different parent income ranks. This enables us to measure the equality of opportunity across parental socioeconomic background, a central focus of empirical research on intergenerational mobility (1⇓–3).
Motivated by the above argument and building on the empirical estimates of the relationship between the parent and child income ranks reported by an emerging line of work using administrative tax data (1), we propose a survey instrument to differentiate among perceptions about mobility outcomes for hypothetical children from different parent income ranks. Specifically, this survey instrument asks the respondents to predict the adult income ranks of children whose parent income ranks at different percentiles of the distribution. Data collected from this survey instrument allow us to estimate the perceived rank–rank relationship “in people’s minds.” Then, by contrasting the perceived rank–rank relationship with its empirical estimates, we present an analytic framework for assessing the public’s (mis-)perceptions about the inequality in mobility chances between children from rich and poor families.
We fielded this instrument on a nationally representative sample of 3,077 adults in the United States. Our data suggest that Americans hold pessimistic perceptions about the equality of economic outcomes between children from rich and poor families. They overestimate the economic prospect for children from rich families and underestimate the economic prospect for those from poor families. This results in an overestimation of the intergenerational persistence in income ranks.
Prior Research on Perceptions of Economic Mobility
Intergenerational mobility indicates the openness, fluidity, and fairness in a society. Promoting the equality of opportunity has become a pressing policy concern, particularly in the recent era of rising inequality. The empirical literature on economic mobility is accompanied by a related literature on perceptions about mobility. The public perceptions about mobility are construed as an ideological condition under which attitudes of and preference toward inequality and redistributive policies are formed. How people view the status of mobility affects their openness or resistance to policy solutions that potentially reduce inequality and promote mobility (9, 10, 13, 20⇓⇓–23).
One strand of research suggests that the general public holds optimistic views on economic mobility in America (9, 11, 12). For example, Americans overestimate the probability that children starting from the bottom can make it to the top of the income distribution and underestimate the probability of a bottom-quintile child remaining at the bottom in America, while their Europeans counterparts hold more pessimistic perceptions about mobility in their countries (9). Another line of work, however, suggests that Americans are actually concerned about economic mobility (15⇓⇓–18) and that Americans have more enduring structural perceptions about mobility than widely assumed (18, 19). Furthermore, Americans’ concerns about the lack of opportunity have played a role in shaping their concerns about economic inequality (13, 24). Growth in economic inequality increases skepticism regarding the opportunity structure in society that, in turn, may motivate support for equity-enhancing policies (18). A detailed literature summary is presented in SI Appendix, section 1.
While previous work has taken important steps to understand the public perceptions of mobility, most of those measures tend to focus on the perceived transition probabilities for children from specific subgroups, such as the likelihood to move from bottom to top or from top to bottom (9, 12). However, these findings are sensitive to whether the socioeconomic spectrum is divided into 5 (25) or 3 (15) strata, whether phrases like “stayed in the bottom” or “moved up” were used (26), and the empirical benchmark against which people’s perceptions are compared (17). Another drawback is that these measures typically involve the calculation of probability, which is prone to cognitive errors by lay people, especially compared with average or expectation-based measures (16, 27, 28). Most importantly, these previous measures tend to focus on mobility chances for 1 or a few specific income groups, such as the top or bottom quintile. They have not examined the differences in perceived mobility prospects across the full spectrum of parent income ranks.
A Rank–Rank-Based Survey Instrument
This study contributes to current scholarship by proposing a survey instrument for measuring the variation in mobility perceptions, which is based on the relationship between parent and child income ranks. We present each respondent with 3 questions of the same format. The question first describes a hypothetical person whose parents’ income ranks at the pth percentile of the income distribution. A picture is also presented to illustrate the income ranking (SI Appendix, section 2). We then ask the respondent to drag a slider on a marked bar to indicate where she thinks this child’s own family income will rank at age 40. Each respondent will answer 3 such questions in which the hypothetical person’s parent income ranks (i.e., p) are drawn randomly without replacement from a total of 9 deciles (i.e.,
This survey instrument has several advantages. First, the question presents a reasonably tractable task to the respondents, as it avoids asking lay people to evaluate complicated transition probabilities. Second, as each respondent is asked to consider mobility outcomes for only 3 hypothetical individuals, each from a different parent income rank, the survey imposes a relatively light cognitive burden. These 2 advantages were confirmed in our pilot study, where we recruited 50 respondents via Amazon Mechanical Turk and asked them to describe their logic of reasoning in answering these questions (SI Appendix, section 3 has details and additional checks).
Most importantly, data collected from this instrument can be used to estimate the perceived rank–rank relationship, which can then be compared against the actual rank–rank relationship to describe the direction and degree of mobility misperception. To do this, for a sample of size n, we pool the answers across individuals to form a total of
Fig. 1 illustrates 4 example cases for this comparison. In Fig. 1, solid (dashed) lines represent the actual (perceived) rank–rank relationship. The area
Illustration of rank–rank lines in perception (dashed) and in reality (solid).
Case A presents an example in which the perceived rank–rank line is parallel to the actual line (
The next 2 cases illustrate scenarios in which the public has misperceptions about the equality of opportunity (
Two important features of this survey instrument are worth noting. First, in principle,
The key takeaway from the 4 example cases illustrated in Fig. 1 is that the problem of measuring the public’s (mis-)perceptions of mobility prospects across the parent income distribution can be reduced to a simpler problem of obtaining 4 parameters:
Data Collection
We collected data from a probability-based representative sample of 3,077 adults in the United States. Participants were recruited during February 2018 via National Opinion Research Center’s AmeriSpeak panel maintained by the Time-Sharing Experiments in the Social Sciences. We randomly assigned the respondents to 3 groups that vary in the attributes of the hypothetical person: (i) a baseline group in which there is no specific description (n = 1,858), (ii) a “college graduate” treatment group in which we describe the person as having a college degree (n = 606), and (iii) a “hard-working” treatment group in which we describe the person as working very hard in life (n = 613). These descriptions were added right after the information on the person’s parent income rank is given. Our analyses are weighted by AmeriSpeak panel weights. Weighted and unweighted sample statistics are presented in SI Appendix, section 4.
For the benchmark of actual mobility, we rely on the rank–rank relationship reported by recent work using tax records (1). These estimates do not suffer from measurement errors that are prevalent in survey data (29). Moreover, unlike other mobility measures, such as the intergenerational elasticity, which tend to be nonlinear, the rank–rank relationship in the United States can be well approximated by a linear line, the slope of which provides a succinct way for quantifying income mobility.
Empirical Results
Baseline Group.
As no additional information of the hypothetical person is given, results from the baseline group reflect the perceptions of overall mobility. Fig. 2 presents the conditional densities of child’s perceived income rank by parent income rank. The 3 horizontal lines at each parent income rank represent the 75th, 50th, and 25th percentiles of the child’s perceived income rank. While the child’s perceived income rank varies at each parent income rank, the median and the upper and lower quartiles of the perceived income rank distribution all increase steadily with parent income rank, showing intergenerational persistence in income ranks.
Conditional density distributions of child’s perceived income rank.
How well does the perceived rank–rank relationship match the reality? Fig. 3 contrasts the perceived rank–rank relationship in our data and the actual rank–rank line. For illustration, we have also plotted 2 auxiliary lines (Fig. 3, light blue dashed lines) indicating perfect income persistence (Fig. 3, diagonal 45° line) and perfect income mobility (Fig. 3, horizontal line where child’s mean rank = 50). A steeper rank–rank slope indicates greater closeness to perfect persistence, and a flatter slope indicates greater closeness to perfect mobility.
Rank–rank relationship in perception and in reality.
The pattern shown in Fig. 3 is akin to Case C in Fig. 1. The 2 lines cross at around the 34th percentile of parent income rank. To the right of this crossing point—that is, for children from families in the middle or upper parts of the income distribution—the public overestimates children’s income ranks. To the left of this crossing point, perceived economic ranks are lower than reality, indicating an underestimation of the economic prospects for children from the lower end of the income spectrum. Observe that
Table 1 quantifies these results.
Estimated model parameters and derived quantities
Between-Group Variations.
We next examine whether the public’s perceptions of mobility vary by respondents’ characteristics. To examine the between-group variations, we estimate a multilevel model predicting the child’s perceived income rank for respondent i and item k (=1, 2, and 3). Level 1 model is
The random intercept (
We present the coefficients predicting the slope in Fig. 4 and the full coefficient estimates in SI Appendix, section 7. Here, the effects of covariates on slope are of particular interest. A positive (negative) coefficient indicates greater (lesser) perceived inequality in mobility chances compared with the reference group. Respondents who are age 18–29, are white, are living in a household with $30,000–$99,999 annual income, own a house or pay some rent, lean liberal, or have a bachelor’s degree are more pessimistic about the equality of mobility prospects across parent income ranks.
Effects of respondent’s characteristics on perceived rank–rank slope (point estimates with 90% CIs). BA, bachelor’s degree; HS, high school.
Fig. 5 demonstrates the perceived rank–rank relationship by respondents’ education, household income, and political ideology. Higher education and income are associated with greater pessimism about mobility, a finding also noted by previous studies (9, 12, 25). Among those without a high school degree, the perceived rank–rank line is only slightly steeper than the reality; respondents with a bachelor’s degree are most pessimistic about the equality of mobility outcomes, particularly for children from the lowest 30% of income distribution. Respondents in all income groups are pessimistic about the equality of mobility prospects, and the perceived rank–rank slope is flattest among those with less than $30,000 annual household income.
Perceived rank–rank relationship by respondent’s education, household income, and political ideology.
Liberals are more pessimistic about the equality of mobility prospects, a finding consistent with prior findings (9, 15, 25). As discussed earlier, our rank–rank measure has the strength of allowing us to differentiate between perceptions of mobility prospects across parent income ranks. For example, here, the results suggest that respondents with different political orientation do not differ much in the perceived mobility for children with high parent income, but their perceptions differ substantially for children from the lower part of the income distribution.
Our analysis and interpretation above have focused on whether between-group differences exist rather than why they exist. The complex mechanisms behind these between-group differences are beyond the scope of this paper, and future research is needed to better understand the patterns of these differences. However, these results also suggest that Americans’ pessimism about the equality of mobility prospects across parent income ranks is quite robust across subgroups of the population.
College Graduate Treatment and Hard-Working Treatment.
Comparing the perceived rank–rank lines in the 2 treatment groups with the baseline group will tell us the extent to which the public perceives a college degree or hard work as a factor for promoting intergenerational mobility. Fig. 6 demonstrates the results. The college degree treatment raises the intercept (P = 0.000) and flattens the slope (P = 0.057) for the rank–rank line. When the hypothetical person has a college degree, respondents now perceive slightly higher-income ranks for children across the parent income spectrum, especially for those in the middle and lower parts. Consistent with the findings from empirical work (30, 31), the perceived rank–rank slope decreases when the hypothetical person has a college degree, but the perceived slope change (0.65–0.56) is much smaller than the change in reality (0.34–0.15) reported by recent empirical work (30). Hence, the public underestimates not only the amount of mobility but also, the contribution of a college degree to mobility. The perceived rank–rank line for the hard-working treatment has a slightly higher intercept (P = 0.086) than the baseline, and there is very small difference in their slopes (P = 0.955).
Perceived rank–rank relationship in baseline and treatment groups.
Some nonlinearity of the rank–rank lines can be observed here: the 3 rank–rank lines are very close to each other at the upper 40% of the distribution but diverge for the lower 60%. Hence, we estimated the perceived slopes restricting to the lower 60% of parent income ranks. The changes in slopes are slightly higher but still very small. The pattern holds when we break down the sample by education and income (SI Appendix, section 8). These results suggest that the public remains pessimistic about the equality of opportunity even when the hypothetical person is assigned attributes that should promote economic mobility. The small treatment effects could also be due to the weakness of the intervention. The explanations behind the public’s pessimism about the role of college in promoting education warrant future research.
Robustness Checks.
Our results are robust to several alternative specifications, including using the median instead of mean of child’s income rank (SI Appendix, section 9), using a nonlinear smooth function to model the rank–rank curve (SI Appendix, section 10), and separating the data by the order in which the items appeared in the survey (SI Appendix, section 11). To test whether the findings are driven by potential misperceptions about income inequality, we provided a subgroup (n = 586) with some factual information on the household income distribution before they answered the original survey questions; this did not change the findings (SI Appendix, section 12 has a detailed discussion).
Discussion and Conclusion
The question of how Americans think about intergenerational mobility draws growing attention from scholars and policy makers who seek to understand its consequences for public opinion, political action, and policy support. In examining mobility perceptions, previous work has mainly focused on the perceived transition probabilities for children from specific positions in the parent income distribution. This study proposes a rank–rank-based survey instrument for measuring public perceptions of the inequality in mobility prospects. The key strengths of this measure are 3-fold. First, this measure differentiates perceived economic outcomes for children across parent income ranks, which enables us to measure the perceptions about the inequality in mobility prospects. Second, the survey item presents the respondents with a relatively simple, tractable task and requires little cognitive burden. Third, the perceived rank–rank line derived from the data can be directly compared with an up-to-date empirical benchmark based on administrative tax data.
In accounting for the differential perceptions of economic outcomes for hypothetical children from different parent income ranks, we have now come to form a more comprehensive picture of mobility perceptions. We conclude that Americans are pessimistic about the equality of economic prospects among children born to rich and poor parents. This finding challenges the prior belief that Americans hold an optimistic view about the openness of the society and is instead consistent with the idea that the everyday experiences of highly unequal opportunity between children from poorer and wealthier families may have shaped how the general public thinks about the opportunity structure of the American society. The results also indicate that the pessimism about the equality of mobility prospects results from their overestimation of income ranks for children from families in the middle and higher ends of the income distribution and their underestimation of income ranks for children from low-income families.
Reading our findings along with recent work on the public beliefs about inequality and mobility (13, 18), we suggest that the once-prevailing belief (that Americans tolerate inequality, because they see great promise in economic mobility) may be misleading. With large-scale, population-representative data, we show that Americans are aware of, and in fact quite pessimistic about, the remarkably unequal distribution of economic outcomes by family background. These findings call for an extended scope of inquiries that bridge the empirical research on economic mobility with research on the social, political, and psychological processes that shape how the public thinks about it. We also highlight the need for policy and political solutions to seriously engage with Americans’ concerns about the equality of opportunity in the society.
Methods
This research was reviewed and approved by the Institutional Review Board at New York University. Informed consent was obtained from all participants.
Acknowledgments
This study received support from the Seed Award from the Institute of Human Development and Social Change at New York University, and the Time-Sharing Experiments for the Social Sciences through NSF Grant 0818839.
Footnotes
- ↵1To whom correspondence may be addressed. Email: siwei.cheng{at}nyu.edu.
Author contributions: S.C. designed research; S.C. and F.W. performed research; S.C. and F.W. analyzed data; and S.C. and F.W. wrote the paper.
The authors declare no conflict of interest.
This article is a PNAS Direct Submission. D.B.G. is a guest editor invited by the Editorial Board.
This article contains supporting information online at www.pnas.org/lookup/suppl/doi:10.1073/pnas.1814688116/-/DCSupplemental.
Published under the PNAS license.
References
- ↵
- ↵
- M. Hout
- ↵
- ↵
- A. Björklund,
- M. Jäntti
- ↵
- M. Jantti et al.
- ↵
- G. Esping-Andersen
- ↵
- S. M. Lipset,
- R. Bendix
- ↵
- J. T. Adams
- ↵
- A. Alesina,
- S. Stantcheva,
- E. Teso
- ↵
- J. Huber,
- W. Form
- ↵
- J. R. Kluegel,
- E. R. Smith
- ↵
- ↵
- L. McCall
- ↵
- H. McClosky,
- J. Zaller
- ↵
- ↵
- L. K. Swan,
- J. R. Chambers,
- M. Heesacker,
- S. S. Nero
- ↵
- S. S. Nero,
- L. K. Swan,
- J. R. Chambers,
- M. Heesacker
- ↵
- L. McCall,
- D. Burk,
- M. Laperrière,
- J. A. Richeson
- ↵
- I. Kirsch,
- H. Braun
- L. McCall
- ↵
- ↵
- M. V. Day,
- S. T. Fiske
- ↵
- K. S. Newman
- ↵
- ↵
- L. McCall,
- L. Kenworthy
- ↵
- ↵
- S. Davidai,
- T. Gilovich
- ↵
- K. Eriksson,
- B. Simpson
- ↵
- ↵
- P. Mitnik,
- V. Bryant,
- M. Weber,
- D. B. Grusky
- ↵
- R. Chetty,
- J. N. Friedman,
- E. Saez,
- N. Turner,
- D. Yagan
- ↵
Citation Manager Formats
Article Classifications
- Social Sciences
- Social Sciences