Skip to main content

Main menu

  • Home
  • Articles
    • Current
    • Special Feature Articles - Most Recent
    • Special Features
    • Colloquia
    • Collected Articles
    • PNAS Classics
    • List of Issues
  • Front Matter
    • Front Matter Portal
    • Journal Club
  • News
    • For the Press
    • This Week In PNAS
    • PNAS in the News
  • Podcasts
  • Authors
    • Information for Authors
    • Editorial and Journal Policies
    • Submission Procedures
    • Fees and Licenses
  • Submit
  • Submit
  • About
    • Editorial Board
    • PNAS Staff
    • FAQ
    • Accessibility Statement
    • Rights and Permissions
    • Site Map
  • Contact
  • Journal Club
  • Subscribe
    • Subscription Rates
    • Subscriptions FAQ
    • Open Access
    • Recommend PNAS to Your Librarian

User menu

  • Log in
  • My Cart

Search

  • Advanced search
Home
Home
  • Log in
  • My Cart

Advanced Search

  • Home
  • Articles
    • Current
    • Special Feature Articles - Most Recent
    • Special Features
    • Colloquia
    • Collected Articles
    • PNAS Classics
    • List of Issues
  • Front Matter
    • Front Matter Portal
    • Journal Club
  • News
    • For the Press
    • This Week In PNAS
    • PNAS in the News
  • Podcasts
  • Authors
    • Information for Authors
    • Editorial and Journal Policies
    • Submission Procedures
    • Fees and Licenses
  • Submit
Research Article

Climate change and the opportunity cost of conflict

View ORCID ProfileKevin R. Roche, Michèle Müller-Itten, David N. Dralle, Diogo Bolster, and View ORCID ProfileMarc F. Müller
  1. aDepartment of Civil and Environmental Engineering and Earth Sciences, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556;
  2. bDepartment of Economics, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556;
  3. cDepartment of Geology, California State University, Sacramento, CA 95819

See allHide authors and affiliations

PNAS January 28, 2020 117 (4) 1935-1940; first published January 13, 2020; https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1914829117
Kevin R. Roche
aDepartment of Civil and Environmental Engineering and Earth Sciences, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556;
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  • ORCID record for Kevin R. Roche
Michèle Müller-Itten
bDepartment of Economics, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556;
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  • For correspondence: mmulleri@nd.edu
David N. Dralle
cDepartment of Geology, California State University, Sacramento, CA 95819
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
Diogo Bolster
aDepartment of Civil and Environmental Engineering and Earth Sciences, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556;
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
Marc F. Müller
aDepartment of Civil and Environmental Engineering and Earth Sciences, University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556;
  • Find this author on Google Scholar
  • Find this author on PubMed
  • Search for this author on this site
  • ORCID record for Marc F. Müller
  1. Edited by B. L. Turner II, Arizona State University, Tempe, AZ, and approved November 21, 2019 (received for review August 26, 2019)

  • Article
  • Figures & SI
  • Info & Metrics
  • PDF
Loading

Significance

There is growing consensus among academics that climate change may amplify the risk of violent conflicts. While underlying mechanisms are poorly understood, negative income shocks associated with climate variability have been long hypothesized to play an important role. We relate recent hydrologic and microeconomic advances to investigate the theoretical foundation of this claim. Results prescribe caution in interpreting empirical relations between climate variability and conflict in the context of climate change. While fighting preferentially occurs during climate anomalies, more frequent anomalies may not yield more conflicts. By shifting the entire distribution of rainfall, climate change effectively redefines the very notion of climate anomaly. Adaptation to this new normal can have a dominant, and often counterintuitive, effect on conflict probability.

Abstract

A growing empirical literature associates climate anomalies with increased risk of violent conflict. This association has been portrayed as a bellwether of future societal instability as the frequency and intensity of extreme weather events are predicted to increase. This paper investigates the theoretical foundation of this claim. A seminal microeconomic model of opportunity costs—a mechanism often thought to drive climate–conflict relationships—is extended by considering realistic changes in the distribution of climate-dependent agricultural income. Results advise caution in using empirical associations between short-run climate anomalies and conflicts to predict the effect of sustained shifts in climate regimes: Although war occurs in bad years, conflict may decrease if agents expect more frequent bad years. Theory suggests a nonmonotonic relation between climate variability and conflict that emerges as agents adapt and adjust their behavior to the new income distribution. We identify 3 measurable statistics of the income distribution that are each unambiguously associated with conflict likelihood. Jointly, these statistics offer a unique signature to distinguish opportunity costs from competing mechanisms that may relate climate anomalies to conflict.

  • violence
  • agriculture
  • rainfall
  • income shock
  • microeconomic theory

Climate change is commonly portrayed as one of the most important potential threats to human, ecosystem, and societal well-being (e.g., ref. 1). Perhaps the most direct of these threats is the purported link between climate anomalies and violent conflicts, a notion that is presently shaping political, military, and popular discourse (2). This attention underscores the need for understanding the institutional, economic, and psychological factors that collectively drive individuals and groups to fight. While there is growing consensus among academics that the relation between climate anomalies and conflicts is robust (3), competing explanations and notable exceptions remain. Interpretation and projection of empirical findings in the context of climate change requires careful theoretical consideration of underlying mechanisms. In this study, we relate hydrologic and microeconomic theory to mechanistically describe how changes in water resource availability might alter the emergence of negative income shocks, a potential driver of conflict that is sensitive to climate change (3).

Why do violent conflicts emerge and persist if they are so destructive? This paradox has long attracted the interest of political scientists and economists. The high cost of violence implies that peace is typically a better (Pareto-improving) alternative, and most grievances are believed to be resolved through bargaining (4). Violence might emerge from a bargaining breakdown that prevents a peaceful redistribution of land or resources (5). Among the suspected causes of bargaining breakdown (see ref. 6) are the absence of institutional or social checks, which creates a disconnect between decision makers and foot soldiers who pay the price for violence; incomplete information, including miscalculations of opponents’ strength or strategic withholding of private knowledge; and the inability to commit to a bargain, for example, due to fluctuations in resource availability. Our analysis focuses on the last factor, because it is perhaps most directly affected by climate change (3, 7), rather than by historical, cultural, institutional, and socioeconomic contexts. A growing empirical literature highlights the link between climate variability and negative income shocks as an important determinant of violence (7, 8): fighting tends to happen during bad years, particularly for nonstate-level conflicts short of civil war that do not require the levels of funding and mobilization necessary for organized armed rebellion (9).

In a seminal paper, Chassang and Padro-i Miquel (10) use an opportunity cost argument to provide a theoretical underpinning to the empirical relation between income shocks and conflict. The basic idea is that attacking diverts productive resources but yields an offensive advantage. There is little to lose in diverting resources to attack in bad years but much to be gained from the expected future returns of captured resources. In bad years, the returns from attack outweigh the returns from peace. This prevents peaceful bargaining over resources, and parties go to war. This causal association between anomalously bad weather shocks and conflict occurrence has been robustly documented in the empirical literature. Motivated by both the theory and the empirical observations, many have argued that opportunity costs may be an important mechanism by which climate change can increase the propensity for conflict (see refs. 3 and 7). More extreme weather events and reduced crop productivity (e.g., ref. 11) might increase the frequency and intensity of income shocks during which fighting tends to occur. This possibility is particularly important to consider in institutionally weak and ethnically fragmented regions where climate most directly impacts livelihoods (12⇓–14)—ironically, regions believed to be particularly vulnerable to future climate change (15).

Two important knowledge gaps remain. First, existing studies look at anomalous weather events, which affect the cost but not the benefit of war. They find that parties go to war in bad years. A changed climate, however, alters the distribution of annual rainfall. This affects the distribution of income, which in turn affects both the costs and benefits of fighting. Drought years will become more frequent as rainfall variability increases, which raises concerns about higher conflict likelihood. However, captured resources will also become less productive, which lowers the incentives for attack. An internally consistent prediction on the conflict impact of climate change has to account for both of these changes in agents’ cost–benefit analysis in a way that, to our knowledge, existing projections do not. Second, competing mechanisms (other than opportunity costs) can explain the observed link between climate anomalies and conflict (see, e.g., ref. 16), and current studies do not conclusively speak to their relative salience. Yet, effective policy design requires an accurate identification of the underlying drivers for conflict.

We address these gaps by linking the opportunity cost model proposed by Chassang and Padro-i Miquel (10) to a parametric distribution of climate-related income that is consistent with the current state of the art in hydrologic and agronomic models (17⇓–19). We perform a comparative statics analysis (20) that accounts for agents’ strategic adjustment to a changed environment. Results yield important, and perhaps counterintuitive, insights on the 2 identified knowledge gaps. First, one must be cautious in using empirical associations between short-run climate anomalies and conflicts to predict the effect of sustained shifts in climate regimes. If precipitation becomes more variable, as climate models predict, conflicts will not necessarily become more frequent. Rather, conflict likelihood can go either up or down, as agents adapt and adjust their response to the new income distribution. Even shifts in climate averages will affect the income variance, and therefore conflict, due to nonlinear processes that link climate to income. Second, we identify 3 measurable statistics of the income distribution that individually have an unambiguous effect on conflict and are jointly sufficient to predict the response of conflict to a change in climate. These testable predictions may help distinguish opportunity costs from competing mechanisms relating climate anomalies to conflicts.

It is important to note that the model is not a tool for making quantitative projections of climate–conflict trends in a specific geopolitical context, particularly given the multiple pathways by which societies can respond to climate or economic shocks (see refs. 6 and 16). Rather, the primary objective of the model is a careful theoretical treatment of opportunity costs as a mechanism often thought to drive the relationship between climate change and conflict. In doing so, we elucidate the rich dynamics, and often counterintuitive outcomes, that emerge even under highly stylized theoretical representations of human behavior and climate (21).

Model Overview

Consider 2 groups of farmers, whose annual income is subject to random rainfall variability and who might fight for control over limited land and labor resources (22). Each year, the decision to attack is taken by weighing the immediate opportunity costs of fighting against future expected returns from the captured resources. The former is given by the current year’s rainfall draw, and the latter is jointly determined by the entire distribution of rainfall, by the probability of victory, and by the endogenous risk of conflict occurring in future years (Materials and Method). Under these conditions, Chassang and Padro-i Miquel (10) show that conflict emerges in bad years, when income falls below a threshold determined by its underlying distribution. Insofar as income is influenced by climate, their model offers a mechanism that can explain the empirical findings that relate climate anomalies to conflicts (16).

We extend the existing model by specifying a rainfall distribution and an income-generating crop function that are analytically tractable and consistent with governing meteorological and hydrological processes (Materials and Methods). Doing so introduces a nonlinear relation between climate and income, whose implications for conflict we discuss in the following section. The parametric distribution of income also allows us to compare predictions of conflict probabilities across distributions by altering parameters to emulate the effect of climate change (Fig. 1). We initially focus on changes in the relative variability of seasonal rainfall, quantified by its coefficient of variation (CVW). The focus on CVW places our study at the intersection of empirical research exploring historic associations between conflict, income, and short-run anomalies of seasonal rainfall (see refs. 7 and 8) and climate modeling research predicting an increase in rainfall variability (e.g., ref. 11). By performing a comparative statics exercise (20), we allow agents to adapt to changed costs and benefits by adjusting their fighting threshold. A changed climate affects both the present opportunity cost and the future returns from conflict, to which agents adapt by shifting the income threshold below which they will decide to fight. For analytical tractability, we favor this rather narrow definition of climate adaptation over a broader interpretation that would allow agents to endogenously optimize income distribution itself, e.g., through crop, policy, and infrastructure selection.

Fig. 1.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 1.

Schematized relation between climate, crop, and conflict models. Moving from left to right, rainfall distributions are related to income distributions via a deterministic model relating seasonal water availability to crop yield, taken as a proxy for income. Income distributions then inform a decision model for conflict. Changes in climate (top to bottom) alter the distribution of water availability, a change that propagates to an altered conflict likelihood.

Mean Climate Can Affect Income Variance

Crop yields do not generally scale linearly with water supply (e.g., ref. 19), and so changes in mean water availability will alter the variance of agricultural income. In particular, a crop chosen to be robust to climate variations will have mean water availability map to a flat region of its yield function (dark blue line in Fig. 2, Top). For such a crop choice, the effect of climate variability on income variability is minimal under existing climate conditions (dark blue line in Fig. 2, Bottom). However, a systematic decrease in water availability will enhance income variability due to the concave nature of the crop yield curve. This effect is particularly pronounced in the low water availability region (low W) of the crop yield curve, where curvature is maximal. There is a broad consensus in climate predictions that points to an increase in rainfall variability and an increase in mean temperatures (see, e.g., ref. 11). The discussion below focuses on changing drought characteristics caused by an increase in rainfall variability. However, the nonlinearity of the climate–income link implies similar conclusions for sustained increases in mean temperature or for excess precipitation (SI Appendix).

Fig. 2.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 2.

Changes in mean climate can cause changes in income variability. A decrease in mean rainfall W (with variance conserved; Top) causes the distribution to map to a more concave region of the crop model (Middle), resulting in distributions of income θ with a larger variance σθ2 (Bottom). This increasing variance compounds the effect of a decreased mean income μθ and increases the coefficient of variation CVθ=σθ/μθ of income. Model parameters (Materials and Methods) are WH=150 mm, θmax= 3 currency units, σW= 69.6 mm, and μW= 270 (dark lines) and 135 mm (light lines).

Nonmonotonic Effect of Climate Variability on Conflict

Despite the stylized nature of the opportunity cost model, changes in the coefficient of variability of water elicit complex nonlinear, and at times nonmonotone, effects on the probability of conflict. Fig. 3 illustrates how conflict probability increases monotonically with climate variability, captured by the coefficient of variation CVW of rainfall, for some parameter combinations (red line), but the relationship becomes nonmonotonic for others (pink line). Indeed, it is possible that conflict prevalence decreases with climate variability for small enough values of CVW and a large enough offensive advantage in the odds of victory (SI Appendix). This behavior suggests that the opportunity cost framework does not consistently predict that a more variable climate will give rise to more prevalent conflicts. This insight is important to consider when using the framework to interpret empirical results. For instance, an empirical study finding an insignificant (Fig. 3, point A) or negative (Fig. 3, point B) relation between climate variability and conflict may not be incompatible with the opportunity cost framework. It also does not dismiss the possibility that a positive relation will emerge as CVW increases under the effect of climate change (as seen in positive slopes at points A′ and B′ in Fig. 3).

Fig. 3.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 3.

Subtle changes in economic parameters can substantially alter the qualitative relationship between conflict probability and climate variability. A slight (2%) increase in the probability of first strike victory π (Materials and Methods) introduces a nonmonotone relationship between the coefficient of variation of seasonal rainfall (CVW) and the predicted probability of conflict (Pwar): a higher climate variability successively decreases and then increases the probability of conflict for a higher value of π (pink line), whereas the relationship remains monotonically increasing for a lower first strike advantage (red line). The shaded area shows the mean (vertical line) and 99% confidence interval of CVW observed for seasonal (3-monthly) rainfall, constructed from daily observations at 671 locations within the United States (23). Model parameters (Materials and Methods) are π1=0.5148 (red), π2=0.5252 (pink), c=0.9, δ=0.9, μW=WH=150 mm, and θmax= 3.

Governing Statistics and Strategic Adaptation

Changes in rainfall variability (CVW) might cause farmers to alter the income threshold below which they will engage in conflict. This adaptation response can strongly influence the probability of conflict (Pwar) as farmers weigh the current opportunity costs of attack against expected future profits. Opportunity costs are lower during a negative climate shock due to decreased crop productivity. Attacking then increases potential future profits for 2 reasons. First, the victor will capture her opponent’s resources and permanently increase her own agricultural profits. Second, triggering a conflict during an income shock hedges against the possibility of a conflict ever occurring in future periods, when opportunity costs are higher on average. In the stark language of our our simple model, both incentives rely on the assumption that the defeated opponent exits the game forever. However, qualitatively similar incentives emerge if the defeated agent temporarily loses his land and ability to fight back, particularly when agents place a high emphasis on short-term profits.

Consequently, the opportunity cost model points to 3 fundamental statistics of the income distribution that govern the relationship between climate change, adaptation response, and conflict: 1) The frequency of income shocks, defined as the probability F(θ∼) that income falls below agents’ conflict threshold θ∼, has a direct effect on the probability of conflict. Any change to the income distribution that increases shock frequency will directly increase Pwar. However, this direct effect also causes war to occur sooner in expectation, thereby reducing the future profits from (current) peace. This gives rise to a second, indirect, effect of an increase in income shock frequency: because peace becomes less advantageous, farmers respond by increasing the income thresholds below which they attack, an adaptation that further exacerbates Pwar. 2) A decrease in mean income E[θ], for instance, associated with a permanent decrease in mean rainfall, makes victory less profitable. Agents adapt to this by adjusting their income threshold for conflict. This causes a decrease in agents’ threshold and, all other statistics being held constant, a decrease in Pwar. 3) Expected income during conflict-inducing shocks E[θ∣θ<θ∼], as a measure of the intensity of income shocks, is proportional to the destructivity of conflicts and affects agents’ incentive to fight through the hedging motive described above. More intense income shocks cause smaller expected losses in income during conflict years. Future conflicts are then less costly on average, which incentivizes agents to postpone fighting. Consequently (and perhaps surprisingly), the anticipation of more intense income shocks has a negative effect on Pwar.

Changes in the 3 income statistics discussed above have independent and consistent (either positive or negative) effects on conflict prevalence, as summarized in Table 1. However, the influence of changes in climate on all 3 income statistics is complex and driven by the specific shape of the distribution that governs interseasonal climate variability. For a realistic distribution of water availability (Materials and Methods), these relations are displayed in Fig. 4, Top, and show that changes in water variability (CVW) elicit different changes in each of the 3 income statistics, in terms of sign and magnitude. In particular, the income shock frequency response can be either positive or negative, depending on the value of CVW and the equilibrium threshold for fighting (Fig. 4, Top, dark blue). In Fig. 4, Bottom, we decompose the overall changes in conflict probability caused by increased climate variability (∂Pwar∂CVW, in red) into its previously described fundamental components (Table 1). Depending on the relative magnitude of the responses, the overall relation between climate variability and conflict may itself be nonmonotone (Figs. 4 and 3, pink). In particular, Fig. 4 shows that the relation can be dominated by agents’ response to changes (dashed) in both mean income (gray dashed) and the intensity of income shocks (i.e., conflict destructivity; light blue dashed). This insight is relevant in the context of recent literature focusing almost exclusively on the effect of changes in the frequency of income shocks on conflicts (e.g., ref. 7). Our theoretical results suggest that farmer adaptation to other climate-driven income statistics, such as the intensity of income shocks, may be equally important to consider.

View this table:
  • View inline
  • View popup
Table 1.

Qualitative effect of the 3 governing statistics of income distribution on the predicted probability of conflict

Fig. 4.
  • Download figure
  • Open in new tab
  • Download powerpoint
Fig. 4.

Components of the climate–income–conflict relationship. (Top) A marginal increase in rainfall variability affects each of the 3 governing statistics S of the income distribution: shock frequency F(θ∼), mean income E[θ], and conflict destructivity cE[θ∣θ<θ∼] (as a measure of shock intensity). The magnitude of each effect is expressed as a partial derivative with respect to CVW. Variables θ, θ∼, c, and CVW indicate annual income (a random variable with cumulative density function F), the income threshold for conflict, the opportunity cost parameter, and the coefficient of variation of rainfall, respectively (Materials and Method). (Bottom) Income shock frequency has a direct and axiomatic impact on the probability of conflict Pwar=F(θ∼) (solid blue). However, changes in all 3 income statistics affect Pwar because agents adapt by changing their income threshold θ∼ (dashed lines; Table 1). The total contribution of these effects determines the nonmonotonic response of Pwar (red), which is also expressed as a partial derivative with respect to CVW. Parameters (Materials and Methods) are π=0.524, c=0.9, δ=0.9, μW=WH= 150 mm, and θmax=3.

Relation to Empirical Regularities

Chassang and Padro-i Miquel (10) point to 2 stylized facts that persistently emerge from the empirical literature on income and conflict: 1) conflicts tend to happen during bad income shocks and 2) conflicts are more prevalent in low-income countries. At first sight, these regularities may appear at odds with our theoretical predictions suggesting that more intense income shocks and lower average income both decrease the propensity for conflict (Table 1).

At a closer look, however, stylized fact 1 is a statement about low individual draws from a given distribution (horizontal direction in Fig. 1), whereas Table 1 concerns sustained shifts in the distribution of income (vertical direction in Fig. 1). In line with ref. 10, conflict occurs in our model when income falls below a certain threshold. Table 1 is saying that a sustained shift in the distribution toward more extreme droughts causes agents to lower that threshold. In other words, agents fight in anomalously dry years for a given distribution, but they think twice about fighting for a given draw if dry years become the new normal.

Regarding the second stylized fact, it is important to point out that the theoretical results in Table 1 concern marginal changes in each income statistic, with the 2 other statistics held constant. Any nonmarginal change in distribution will also change the other 2 statistics because they are themselves determined by the threshold θ∼. For instance, scaling annual income by a constant factor affects all 3 statistics in a way that they exactly cancel out (SI Appendix). This gives rise to the invariance of Pwar to income scaling noted by Chassang and Padro-i Miquel (10). Similarly, a constant upward shift in income results in a decrease in Pwar under reasonable assumptions, as shown in SI Appendix. The reality may be best captured by a combination of the 2: rich countries have more income and also less volatile income. The model would then indeed predict a lower probability of war.

Practical Implications

The theoretical arguments in this paper are a strong simplification of reality. The economic incentives we discuss represent a small subset of the social, political, and historical processes that together give rise to violent conflicts. Nonetheless, they capture important dynamics through which climate-related income shocks may cause rational agents to be amenable to conflict. Theoretical insights from the model have 3 important implications that can guide policy and empirical research.

First, it is important to distinguish climate from income variability when examining their implications for conflicts. The nonlinear and highly local effect of climate on agricultural income has been highlighted in several studies (e.g., refs. 24 and 25) and has a strong qualitative impact on conflict incentives. It emerges from a combination of natural (timing of rain events (26)), technical (crop choice (27)), economic (agricultural prices (28)), and institutional (insurance and regulation (29)) processes that were often put in place precisely to decouple income from climate variability (30). However, as climate variability begins to exceed historical ranges, these hedging mechanisms may become less effective. For instance, a crop that is adapted to a certain precipitation range will be more susceptible to variation at lower rainfall levels due to the increased curvature of the crop function (Fig. 2). This curvature causes a change in mean climate to affect the variability of income, which propagates to conflict incentives. This stylized example highlights the necessity of a careful empirical characterization of the climate–income relationship to understand implications for conflicts.

Second, theoretical results may inform empirical research that seeks to disentangle opportunity cost motives from other mechanisms that predict conflict during bad years. Alternative hypotheses (see ref. 16) include weakened government structures (caused by a drop in tax revenue), increased (perceived) inequality, and climate-induced migration, as well as cognitive and physiological factors that contribute to aggression. All of these competing mechanisms also predict that current conflict is negatively correlated with current income. However, since none of the alternative explanations are forward-looking, they would predict either no, or perhaps a negative, correlation between current conflict and the income in prior years (see discussion in SI Appendix). Opportunity costs are different: if agents update their belief about future incomes in a Bayesian way (some evidence of it is given in ref. 31), a sequence of good years leads agents to expect greater gains from attack and thus renders them more, not less, aggressive in subsequent years. This is a testable implication that is unique to the opportunity cost argument and can thus serve to empirically assess its explanatory power.

Finally, caution must be exercised in using microeconomic income shock arguments to interpret empirical analyses of historic data and draw extrapolations for climate change. While the model does suggest a positive correlation between weather anomalies and conflict, it does not support the argument that conflicts will always be more prevalent if these anomalies occur more frequently due to climate change. Rather, the theory suggests a complex, and potentially nonmonotonic, relation between climate variability and conflict. This complexity emerges both from nonlinear climate to income relationships and from strategic adaptation by agents to a changing income distribution. By affecting the entire distribution of climate, climate change will effectively define a new normal. Agents strategically adapt to multiple facets of climate change by adjusting their response to income variability. In doing so, they redefine the very notion of climate anomalies and associated negative income shocks as they pertain to climate-related conflicts.

Materials and Methods

Conflict.

Two groups of farmers occupy a common territory over an infinite number of periods (growing seasons). Three productive inputs determine crop yields and agricultural income: land, labor, and water availability. Land and labor are equitably distributed between the 2 players (unequal distribution can be resolved through peaceful bargaining (10)) and constant across periods. However, rainfall varies randomly across periods, following a known probability distribution and affecting both groups identically. In each period, both groups observe rainfall and either group can unilaterally launch an attack to seize permanent control of the entire territory. If neither group attacks, peace prevails, all labor is put to productive use, and both groups keep control of their own land and labor. If either side attacks, violence prevails, and both groups divert a fixed share c of labor to armed conflict. In a 1-sided attack, the attacker has an offensive advantage and wins with probability π>0.5. In a simultaneous attack, both groups win with equal probability. The winner controls the entire territory forever, and the loser exits the game.

The decision to attack in each season t relies on weighing the expected future benefits of victory against the current opportunity cost of conflict. Peace will prevail if the expected returns of peace, E[P], are larger than the expected returns of launching a surprise attack, E[W]: θ t︷current season + δ VP︷future seasons ︸E[P] > π 2θt(1−c)︷current season + πδVV︷future seasons︸E[W],[1]where θt is an income sampled from the PDF f(θ), VP are the future expected returns of peacefully farming one’s own land (discounted by a constant factor, δ), π is the probability of victory in a surprise attack, c is the fractional cost of the present season’s production devoted to war, and VV represents the expected returns of victory (discounted by δ). The factor 2 appears because the victorious farmer obtains both plots of land.

A key characteristic of the model is that the current opportunity cost is driven by an individual draw θ, while the future benefits are affected by the entire probability distribution F of income. Groups go to war when current income falls below a threshold θ∼, which depends on economic parameters and the distribution F. Chassang and Padro-i Miquel (10) show that VV=2E[θ]/(1−δ), where E[] is the expectation operator. In contrast, VP is an implicit equation that depends on the attack threshold, θ∼, defined as the θ at which E[P]=E [W] (SI Appendix). An implicit expression for θ∼ is found by substituting VV and VP into 1, setting E[W]=E[P], and rearrangingθ∼=δ1−2P(1−c)(2P−1)E[θ]1−δ+F(θ∼)⋅cE[θ∣θ<θ∼]1−δ(1−F(θ∼)),[2]where F(θ∼) = ∫0θ∼f(x)dx and E[ ∣] is the conditional expectation operator. The probability of war in any season is simply Pwar=F(θ∼).

Climate, Water Availability, and Crop Productivity.

We assume that both farmer groups are subject to the same crop productivity (θt) governed by seasonal water volume, W [L], normalized by catchment area. We use a model for lumped crop yield potential [M L−2] as a proxy for agricultural income, θ. Water supply is assumed to be the yield-limiting factor (19), allowing us to map f(θ) directly to the distribution of water supply, fW(W). Although additional factors such as intraseasonal dry spells are known to affect crop yields, we do not include them in our model since our principal aim is to maintain emphasis on the human decision model, and yields have been shown to be primarily determined by total precipitation. Based on observations reported in ref. 19, we specify a parsimonious boundary function relation for yield:θ=θmax⋅WW+WH,[3]where WH is a half-saturation constant and θmax is the maximum productivity. We assume land to be spatially homogeneous and situated in a watershed sufficiently flat for hydrologic conditions to be driven by vertical rainfall infiltration into the soil layer (32). We assume that water is derived from rainfall, allowing fW(W) to be approximated using a Gamma distribution (18) (SI Appendix). Under these assumptions, an exact expression for f(θ) isf(θ)=exp−θ(θmax−θ)(μW WH−1)CVW2θ(θmax−θ)(μW WH−1)CVW21CVW2θθmax(θmax−θ) Γ1CVW2,[4]where μW [L] and CVW [–] are the mean and coefficient of variation of fW(W), respectively, and Γ(−) is the Gamma function.

Response of Pwar to Changing Water Resources.

We determine the response of Pwar=F(θ∼) to water variability by numerically differentiating F(θ∼) with respect to CVW:dPwardCVW =∂Pwar∂CVW︸mechanistic effect+∑n=13∂Pwar∂θ∼⋅∂θ∼∂Sn⋅∂Sn∂CVW︸farmer adaptation,[5]where Sn∈{E[θ],F(θ∼),E[θ∣θ<θ∼]} are the 3 fundamental statistics that govern θ∼ (Eq. 2). Total sensitivity of Pwar is partitioned into direct and adaptation effects (following Eq. 5 in ref. 7). Changes in fW(W) alter the probability of an income shock in a given period (direct effect), thereby changing the probability that farmers will attack, F(θ∼). The direct change to f(θ) also alters the expected returns from peace, VP (SI Appendix). Farmers therefore adapt θ∼ to a value that again satisfies Eq. 1 with equality (adaptation effect).

Data Availability Statement.

All results and figures in this paper can be reproduced from the equations herein.

Acknowledgments

K.R.R., M.M.-I., D.B., and M.F.M. acknowledge support from the National Science Foundation Coupled Natural Systems Human program award 1824951. We are grateful to Patrick Regan, Lakshmi Iyer, and 2 anonymous reviewers for helpful and constructive comments.

Footnotes

  • ↵1K.R.R. and M.M.-I. contributed equally to this work.

  • ↵2To whom correspondence may be addressed. Email: mmulleri{at}nd.edu.
  • Author contributions: M.M.-I. and M.F.M. designed research; K.R.R., M.M.-I., D.N.D., D.B., and M.F.M. performed research; and K.R.R., M.M.-I., and M.F.M. wrote the paper.

  • The authors declare no competing interest.

  • This article is a PNAS Direct Submission.

  • This article contains supporting information online at https://www.pnas.org/lookup/suppl/doi:10.1073/pnas.1914829117/-/DCSupplemental.

Published under the PNAS license.

References

  1. ↵
    1. D. J. Dokken et al.
    1. W. Neil Adger, et al.
    , “Human security” in Climate Change 2014: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability. Part A: Global and Sectoral Aspects. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, D. J. Dokken et al., Eds. (Cambridge University Press, 2014), pp. 755–791.
  2. ↵
    1. W. Barnaby
    . Do nations go to war over water? Nature, 458, 282–283 (2009).
    OpenUrlCrossRefPubMed
  3. ↵
    1. K. J. Mach et al.
    , Climate as a risk factor for armed conflict. Nature 571, 193–197 (2019).
    OpenUrl
  4. ↵
    1. J. D. Fearon,
    2. D. D. Laitin
    , Explaining interethnic cooperation. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 90, 715–735 (1996).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  5. ↵
    1. J. D. Fearon
    , Rationalist explanations for war. Int. Organ. 49, 379–414 (1995).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  6. ↵
    1. C. Blattman,
    2. E. Miguel
    , Civil war. J. Econ. Lit. 48, 3–57 (2010).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  7. ↵
    1. M. Burke,
    2. S. M. Hsiang,
    3. E. Miguel
    , Climate and conflict. Annu. Rev. Econ. 7, 577–617 (2015).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  8. ↵
    1. E. Miguel,
    2. S. Satyanath,
    3. E. Sergenti
    , Economic shocks and civil conflict: An instrumental variables approach. J. Polit. Econ. 112, 725–753 (2004).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  9. ↵
    1. C. S. Hendrix,
    2. I. Salehyan
    , Climate change, rainfall, and social conflict in Africa. J. Peace Res. 49, 35–50 (2012).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  10. ↵
    1. S. Chassang,
    2. G. Padro-i Miquel
    , Economic shocks and civil war. Q. J. Polit. Sci., 4, 211–228 (2009).
    OpenUrl
  11. ↵
    1. C. B. Field, et al.
    1. J. R. Porter et al.
    , “Food security and food production systems” in Climate Change 2014: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability. Part A: Global and Sectoral Aspects. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel of Climate Change, C. B. Field, et al. Eds. (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom, 2014), pp. 485–533.
  12. ↵
    1. N. Von Uexkull,
    2. M. Croicu,
    3. H. Fjelde,
    4. H. Buhaug
    , Civil conflict sensitivity to growing-season drought. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 113, 12391–12396 (2016).
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  13. ↵
    1. C.-F. Schleussner,
    2. J. F. Donges,
    3. R. V. Donner,
    4. H. J. Schellnhuber
    , Armed-conflict risks enhanced by climate-related disasters in ethnically fractionalized countries. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 113, 9216–9221 (2016).
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  14. ↵
    1. K. Eck
    , The law of the land: Communal conflict and legal authority. J. Peace Res. 51, 441–454 (2014).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  15. ↵
    1. M. Dell,
    2. B. F. Jones,
    3. B. A. Olken
    , Temperature shocks and economic growth: Evidence from the last half century. Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 4, 66–95 (2012).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  16. ↵
    1. S. M. Hsiang,
    2. M. Burke,
    3. E. Miguel
    , Quantifying the influence of climate on human conflict. Science 341, 1235367 (2013).
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  17. ↵
    1. G. Botter,
    2. S. Basso,
    3. I. Rodriguez-Iturbe,
    4. A. Rinaldo
    , Resilience of river flow regimes. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 110, 12925–12930 (2013).
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  18. ↵
    1. D. Dralle,
    2. N. Karst,
    3. M. Müller,
    4. G. Vico,
    5. S. E. Thompson
    , Stochastic modelling of inter-annual variation of hydrologic variables. Geophys. Res. Lett. 44, 7285–7294 (2017).
    OpenUrl
  19. ↵
    1. M. K. van Ittersum et al.
    , Yield gap analysis with local to global relevance—A review. Field Crop. Res. 143, 4–17 (2013).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  20. ↵
    1. A. Mas-Colell,
    2. M. D. Whinston,
    3. J. R. Green
    , Microeconomic Theory (Oxford University Press, New York, 1995).
  21. ↵
    1. M. F. Müller,
    2. M. C. Levy
    , Complementary vantage points: Integrating hydrology and economics for sociohydrologic knowledge generation. Water Resour. Res. 55, 2549–2571 (2019).
    OpenUrl
  22. ↵
    1. J. Dell’Angelo,
    2. P. D’Odorico,
    3. M. C. Rulli
    , The neglected costs of water peace. Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Water 5, e1316 (2018).
    OpenUrl
  23. ↵
    1. N. Addor,
    2. A. J. Newman,
    3. N. Mizukami,
    4. M. P. Clark
    , The camels data set: Catchment attributes and meteorology for large-sample studies. Hydrol. Earth Syst. Sci. 21, 5293–5313 (2017).
    OpenUrl
  24. ↵
    1. W. Schlenker,
    2. M. J. Roberts
    , Nonlinear temperature effects indicate severe damages to us crop yields under climate change. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 106, 15594–15598 (2009).
    OpenUrlAbstract/FREE Full Text
  25. ↵
    1. M. Couttenier,
    2. R. Soubeyran
    , Drought and civil war in sub-Saharan Africa. Econ. J. 124, 201–244 (2013).
    OpenUrl
  26. ↵
    1. G. Vico,
    2. A. Porporato
    , From rainfed agriculture to stress-avoidance irrigation: I. A generalized irrigation scheme with stochastic soil moisture. Adv. Water Resour. 34, 263–271 (2011).
    OpenUrl
  27. ↵
    1. M. Auffhammer,
    2. T. A. Carleton
    , Regional crop diversity and weather shocks in India. Asian Dev. Rev. 35, 113–130 (2018).
    OpenUrl
  28. ↵
    1. N. Berman,
    2. M. Couttenier
    , External shocks, internal shots: The geography of civil conflicts. Rev. Econ. Stat. 97, 758–776 (2015).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
  29. ↵
    1. S. Di Falco,
    2. F. Adinolfi,
    3. M. Bozzola,
    4. F. Capitanio
    , Crop insurance as a strategy for adapting to climate change. J. Agric. Econ. 65, 485–504 (2014).
    OpenUrl
  30. ↵
    1. C. B. Field, et al.
    1. M. Chambwera et al.
    , “Economics of adaptation” in Climate Change 2014: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability. Part A: Global and Sectoral Aspects. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel of Climate Change, C. B. Field, et al., Eds. (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom, 2014), pp. 945–977.
  31. ↵
    1. T. Deryugina
    , How do people update? The effects of local weather fluctuations on beliefs about global warming. Clim. Change. 118, 397–416 (2013).
    OpenUrl
  32. ↵
    1. I. Rodriguez-Iturbe,
    2. A. Porporato,
    3. L. Ridolfi,
    4. V. Isham,
    5. D. R. Coxi
    , Probabilistic modelling of water balance at a point: The role of climate, soil and vegetation. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. 455, 3789–3805.(1999).
    OpenUrlCrossRef
PreviousNext
Back to top
Article Alerts
Email Article

Thank you for your interest in spreading the word on PNAS.

NOTE: We only request your email address so that the person you are recommending the page to knows that you wanted them to see it, and that it is not junk mail. We do not capture any email address.

Enter multiple addresses on separate lines or separate them with commas.
Climate change and the opportunity cost of conflict
(Your Name) has sent you a message from PNAS
(Your Name) thought you would like to see the PNAS web site.
CAPTCHA
This question is for testing whether or not you are a human visitor and to prevent automated spam submissions.
Citation Tools
Climate change and the opportunity cost of conflict
Kevin R. Roche, Michèle Müller-Itten, David N. Dralle, Diogo Bolster, Marc F. Müller
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences Jan 2020, 117 (4) 1935-1940; DOI: 10.1073/pnas.1914829117

Citation Manager Formats

  • BibTeX
  • Bookends
  • EasyBib
  • EndNote (tagged)
  • EndNote 8 (xml)
  • Medlars
  • Mendeley
  • Papers
  • RefWorks Tagged
  • Ref Manager
  • RIS
  • Zotero
Request Permissions
Share
Climate change and the opportunity cost of conflict
Kevin R. Roche, Michèle Müller-Itten, David N. Dralle, Diogo Bolster, Marc F. Müller
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences Jan 2020, 117 (4) 1935-1940; DOI: 10.1073/pnas.1914829117
del.icio.us logo Digg logo Reddit logo Twitter logo CiteULike logo Facebook logo Google logo Mendeley logo
  • Tweet Widget
  • Facebook Like
  • Mendeley logo Mendeley

Article Classifications

  • Social Sciences
  • Sustainability Science
  • Physical Sciences
  • Environmental Sciences
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences: 117 (4)
Table of Contents

Submit

Sign up for Article Alerts

Jump to section

  • Article
    • Abstract
    • Model Overview
    • Mean Climate Can Affect Income Variance
    • Nonmonotonic Effect of Climate Variability on Conflict
    • Governing Statistics and Strategic Adaptation
    • Relation to Empirical Regularities
    • Practical Implications
    • Materials and Methods
    • Acknowledgments
    • Footnotes
    • References
  • Figures & SI
  • Info & Metrics
  • PDF

You May Also be Interested in

Smoke emanates from Japan’s Fukushima nuclear power plant a few days after tsunami damage
Core Concept: Muography offers a new way to see inside a multitude of objects
Muons penetrate much further than X-rays, they do essentially zero damage, and they are provided for free by the cosmos.
Image credit: Science Source/Digital Globe.
Water from a faucet fills a glass.
News Feature: How “forever chemicals” might impair the immune system
Researchers are exploring whether these ubiquitous fluorinated molecules might worsen infections or hamper vaccine effectiveness.
Image credit: Shutterstock/Dmitry Naumov.
Venus flytrap captures a fly.
Journal Club: Venus flytrap mechanism could shed light on how plants sense touch
One protein seems to play a key role in touch sensitivity for flytraps and other meat-eating plants.
Image credit: Shutterstock/Kuttelvaserova Stuchelova.
Illustration of groups of people chatting
Exploring the length of human conversations
Adam Mastroianni and Daniel Gilbert explore why conversations almost never end when people want them to.
Listen
Past PodcastsSubscribe
Horse fossil
Mounted horseback riding in ancient China
A study uncovers early evidence of equestrianism in ancient China.
Image credit: Jian Ma.

Similar Articles

Site Logo
Powered by HighWire
  • Submit Manuscript
  • Twitter
  • Facebook
  • RSS Feeds
  • Email Alerts

Articles

  • Current Issue
  • Special Feature Articles – Most Recent
  • List of Issues

PNAS Portals

  • Anthropology
  • Chemistry
  • Classics
  • Front Matter
  • Physics
  • Sustainability Science
  • Teaching Resources

Information

  • Authors
  • Editorial Board
  • Reviewers
  • Subscribers
  • Librarians
  • Press
  • Cozzarelli Prize
  • Site Map
  • PNAS Updates
  • FAQs
  • Accessibility Statement
  • Rights & Permissions
  • About
  • Contact

Feedback    Privacy/Legal

Copyright © 2021 National Academy of Sciences. Online ISSN 1091-6490