Political leadership, climate policy, and renewable energy

March 27, 2023
120 (14) e2301291120
Research Article
Political leadership has limited impact on fossil fuel taxes and subsidies
Cesar B. Martinez-Alvarez, Chad Hazlett [...] Michael L. Ross
Reply
Reply to van den Bergh and Savin: Fossil fuel taxes are politically hard to change
Cesar B. Martinez-Alvarez, Chad Hazlett [...] Michael L. Ross
Martinez-Alvarez et al. (1) conclude that the impact of political leaders on carbon pricing has been limited. Their study has, however, two serious shortcomings: 1) It excludes the 6-y period since the Paris Agreement entered into force (on 4 November 2016), during which many jurisdictions implemented or strengthened carbon pricing; and 2) it limits itself to gasoline taxes while not accounting for genuine carbon pricing, notably applied to large industrial emitters. Among others, it ignores the European Union's emissions-trading system (EU-ETS), the most successful carbon-pricing instrument worldwide, with a price fluctuating around 80€/TCO2 since early 2021. In effect, the study focuses on emissions of fossil-fuel use by transport, representing only some 15% of global emissions. Moreover, since general fuel taxes are not proportional to carbon content of fuels, they provide an inaccurate incentive for CO2 emissions reduction. Finally, the study’s use of ordinary least squares may have biased its results as it is sensitive to outliers—visible in the plots of average monthly changes in fuel taxes (Supporting Information). The literature suggests using least absolute deviation or quantile regression as these avoid assumptions of homoscedasticity and normally distributed errors. Altogether, the pessimistic policy conclusion rests upon feeble grounds.
Next, the authors’ advice is to shift the policy focus to subsidies for renewable energy. This is unconvincing as they did not undertake a comparable analysis for such subsidies while five substantive arguments plead against them. First, the pace of renewable-energy diffusion will be insufficient to meet the Paris targets without major changes in production and consumption structures (2). Second, renewables’ infrastructure requires considerable fossil-fuel inputs that will contribute to CO2 emissions (3). Third, production-related emissions of renewables differ between technologies and countries (4). Since without carbon pricing their sales prices will not reflect such differences, users are not encouraged to minimize life-cycle emissions. Fourth, studies show that carbon pricing is more effective in both encouraging renewables and reducing net emissions (5). Fifth, subsidies promote energy/carbon rebound, estimated at the macroscale to equal possibly 50 to 100% (6). Carbon pricing appears to be the only effective way to limit rebound (7). Given these considerations, it is hardly surprising that historical absence of carbon pricing resulted in low-carbon sources displacing only one-tenth of fossil-fuel-generated electricity (8).
Renewable subsidies are thus a far cry from effective climate policy. The fundamental reason is that climate solutions are prone to free riding: Sacrifices are (perceived as) large, while gains are uncertain, small, and delayed—for both individuals and countries. The EU-ETS demonstrates that a supranational approach harmonizing national climate policies is the way forward to overcome free riding. The EU could invite the United States and China to join its ETS (9). This would simplify negotiations to only three partners—compared to almost 200 countries in post-Paris negotiations under auspices of the United Nations. The resulting China-EU-US climate club with a joint carbon price and border tariff might trigger a domino effect (10). Indeed, few countries would want to remain outside such a powerful club. This is arguably the most realistic scenario for solving climate change.

Acknowledgments

ERC Grant 741087 from the European Research Council in the European Union’s Horizon 2020 program provided financial support.

Author contributions

J.C.J.M.v.d.B. and I.S. wrote the paper.

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interest.

References

1
C. B. Martinez-Alvarez, C. Hazlett, P. Mahdavi, M. L. Ross, Political leadership has limited impact on fossil fuel taxes and subsidies. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 119, e2208024119 (2022).
2
A. Arvesen, R. M. Bright, E. G. Hertwich, Considering only first-order effects? How simplifications lead to unrealistic technology optimism in climate change mitigation. Energy Policy 39, 7448–7454 (2011).
3
A. Slameršak, G. Kallis, D. W. O’Neill, Energy requirements and carbon emissions for a low-carbon energy transition. Nat. Commun. 13, 6932 (2022).
4
F. Liu, J. van den Bergh, Differences in CO2 emissions of solar PV production among technologies and regions: Application to China, EU and USA. Energy Policy 138, 111234 (2020).
5
K. Gugler, A. Haxhimusa, M. Liebensteiner, Effectiveness of climate policies: Carbon pricing vs. subsidizing renewables. J. Environ. Econ. Manage. 106, 102405 (2021).
6
P. E. Brockway, S. R. Sorrell, G. Semieniuk, M. K. Heun, V. Court, Energy efficiency and economy-wide rebound effects: A review of the evidence and its implications. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 141, 110781 (2021).
7
J. C. J. M. van den Bergh, Energy conservation more effective with rebound policy. Environ. Resour. Econ. 48, 43–58 (2011).
8
R. York, Do alternative energy sources displace fossil fuels? Nat. Clim. Change 2, 441–443 (2012).
9
J. C. J. M. van den Bergh et al., A dual-track transition to global carbon pricing. Clim. Policy 20, 1057–1069 (2020).
10
S. Tagliapietra, G. B. Wolff, Form a climate club: United States, European Union and China. Nature 591, 526–528 (2021).

Information & Authors

Information

Published in

The cover image for PNAS Vol.120; No.14
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
Vol. 120 | No. 14
April 4, 2023
PubMed: 36972438

Classifications

Submission history

Published online: March 27, 2023
Published in issue: April 4, 2023

Acknowledgments

ERC Grant 741087 from the European Research Council in the European Union’s Horizon 2020 program provided financial support.
Author contributions
J.C.J.M.v.d.B. and I.S. wrote the paper.
Competing interests
The authors declare no competing interest.

Authors

Affiliations

Institute of Environmental Science and Technology, Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Bellaterra 08193, Spain
ICREA, Barcelona 08010, Spain
School of Business and Economics, VU University Amsterdam, Amsterdam 1081 HV, The Netherlands
Institute for Environmental Studies, VU University Amsterdam, Amsterdam 1081 HV, The Netherlands
Institute of Environmental Science and Technology, Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Bellaterra 08193, Spain
Graduate School of Economics and Management, Ural Federal University, Yekaterinburg 620075, Russian Federation

Notes

1
To whom correspondence may be addressed. Email: [email protected].

Metrics & Citations

Metrics

Note: The article usage is presented with a three- to four-day delay and will update daily once available. Due to ths delay, usage data will not appear immediately following publication. Citation information is sourced from Crossref Cited-by service.


Altmetrics




Citations

Export the article citation data by selecting a format from the list below and clicking Export.

Cited by

    Loading...

    View Options

    View options

    PDF format

    Download this article as a PDF file

    DOWNLOAD PDF

    Figures

    Tables

    Media

    Share

    Share

    Share article link

    Share on social media